The
human brain is divided into two hemispheres–left and right. Scientists
continue to explore how some cognitive functions tend to be dominated by
one side or the other; that is, how they are lateralized.
The lateralization of brain function is the tendency for some neural functions or cognitive processes to be specialized to one side of the brain or the other. The medial longitudinal fissure separates the human brain into two distinct cerebral hemispheres, connected by the corpus callosum.
Although the macrostructure of the two hemispheres appears to be almost
identical, different composition of neuronal networks allows for
specialized function that is different in each hemisphere.
Lateralization of brain structures is based on general trends expressed
in healthy patients; however, there are numerous counterexamples to each
generalization. Each human's brain develops differently leading to
unique lateralization in individuals. This is different from
specialization as lateralization refers only to the function of one
structure divided between two hemispheres. Specialization is much easier
to observe as a trend since it has a stronger anthropological history. The best example of an established lateralization is that of Broca's and Wernicke's areas where both are often found exclusively on the left hemisphere. These areas frequently correspond to handedness,
however, meaning that the localization of these areas is regularly
found on the hemisphere corresponding to the dominant hand (anatomically
on the opposite side). Function lateralization, such as semantics, intonation, accentuation, and prosody, has since been called into question and largely been found to have a neuronal basis in both hemispheres. Another example is that each hemisphere in the brain tends to represent one side of the body. In the cerebellum this is the same bodyside, but in the forebrain this is predominantly the contralateral side.
Lateralized functions
Language
Language
functions such as grammar, vocabulary and literal meaning are typically
lateralized to the left hemisphere, especially in right-handed
individuals.
While language production is left-lateralized in up to 90% of
right-handers, it is more bilateral, or even right-lateralized, in
approximately 50% of left-handers.
Broca's area and Wernicke's area areas associated with the production of speech and comprehension of speech, respectively, are located in the left cerebral hemisphere for about 95% of right-handers, but about 70% of left-handers.
Sensory processing
The
processing of basic sensory information is lateralized by being divided
into left and right sides of the body or the space around the body.
In vision, about half the neurons of the optic nerve
from each eye cross to project to the opposite hemisphere and about
half do not cross to project to the hemisphere on the same side. This means that the left side of the visual field is processed largely by the visual cortex of the right hemisphere and vice versa for the right side of the visual field.
Because of this functional division of the left and right sides
of the body and of the space that surrounds it, the processing of
information in the sensory cortices is essentially identical. That is,
the processing of visual and auditory stimuli, spatial manipulation, facial perception, and artistic ability are represented bilaterally. Numerical estimation, comparison and online calculation depend on bilateral parietal regions
while exact calculation and fact retrieval are associated with left
parietal regions, perhaps due to their ties to linguistic processing.
Value systems
Rather
than just being a series of places where different brain modules occur,
there are running similarities in the kind of function seen in each
side, for instance how right-side impairment of drawing ability making
patients draw the parts of the subject matter with wholly incoherent
relationships, or where the kind of left-side damage seen in language
impairment not damaging the patient's ability to catch the significance
of intonation in speech. This has led Iain McGilchrist to say that the two hemispheres as having different value systems,
where the left hemisphere tends to reduce complex matters such as
ethics to rules and measures, where the right hemisphere is disposed to
the holistic and metaphorical.
Clinical significance
Depression
is linked with a hyperactive right hemisphere, with evidence of
selective involvement in "processing negative emotions, pessimistic
thoughts and unconstructive thinking styles", as well as vigilance,
arousal and self-reflection, and a relatively hypoactive left
hemisphere, "specifically involved in processing pleasurable
experiences" and "relatively more involved in decision-making
processes".
Additionally, "left hemisphere lesions result in an omissive response
bias or error pattern whereas right hemisphere lesions result in a
commissive response bias or error pattern." The delusional misidentification syndromes, reduplicative paramnesia and Capgras delusion are also often the result of right hemisphere lesions.
Hemisphere damage
Damage
to either the right or left hemisphere, and its resulting deficits
provide insight into the function of the damaged area. Left hemisphere
damage has many effects on language production and perception. Damage or
lesions to the right hemisphere can result in a lack of emotional prosody
or intonation when speaking. Right hemisphere damage also has grave
effects on understanding discourse. People with damage to the right
hemisphere have a reduced ability to generate inferences, comprehend and
produce main concepts, and a reduced ability to manage alternative
meanings. Furthermore, people with right hemisphere damage often exhibit
discourse that is abrupt and perfunctory or verbose and excessive. They
can also have pragmatic deficits in situations of turn taking, topic
maintenance and shared knowledge.
Lateral brain damage can also affect visual perceptual spatial
resolution. People with left hemisphere damage may have impaired
perception of high resolution, or detailed, aspects of an image. People
with right hemisphere damage may have impaired perception of low
resolution, or big picture, aspects of an image.
Plasticity
If
a specific region of the brain, or even an entire hemisphere, is
injured or destroyed, its functions can sometimes be assumed by a
neighboring region in the same hemisphere or the corresponding region in
the other hemisphere, depending upon the area damaged and the patient's
age.
When injury interferes with pathways from one area to another,
alternative (indirect) connections may develop to communicate
information with detached areas, despite the inefficiencies.
Broca's aphasia
Broca's aphasia is a specific type of expressive aphasia and is so named due to the aphasia that results from damage or lesions to the Broca's area
of the brain, that exists most commonly in the left inferior frontal
hemisphere. Thus, the aphasia that develops from the lack of functioning
of the Broca's area is an expressive and non-fluent aphasia. It is
called 'non-fluent' due the issues that arise because Broca's area is
critical for language pronunciation and production. The area controls
some motor aspects of speech production and articulation of thoughts to
words and as such lesions to the area result in the specific non-fluent
aphasia.
Wernicke's aphasia
Wernicke's aphasia
is the result of damage to the area of the brain that is commonly in
the left hemisphere above the sylvian fissure. Damage to this area
causes primarily a deficit in language comprehension. While the ability
to speak fluently with normal melodic intonation is spared, the language produced by a person with Wernicke's aphasia is riddled with semantic
errors, and may sound nonsensical to the listener. Wernicke's aphasia
is characterized by phonemic paraphasias, neologism or jargon. Another
characteristic of a person with Wernicke's aphasia is that they are
unconcerned by the mistakes that they are making.
Society and culture
Misapplication
Terence Hines
states that the research on brain lateralization is valid as a research
program, though commercial promoters have applied it to promote
subjects and products far outside the implications of the research. For example, the implications of the research have no bearing on psychological interventions such as EMDR and neurolinguistic programming, brain-training equipment, or management training.
Pop psychology
The
oversimplification of lateralization in pop psychology. This belief was
widely held even in the scientific community for some years.
Some popularizations oversimplify the science about lateralization,
by presenting the functional differences between hemispheres as being
more absolute than is actually the case.
Sex differences
In the 19th century and to a lesser extent the 20th, it was thought
that each side of the brain was associated with a specific gender: the
left corresponding with masculinity and the right with femininity and
each half could function independently.
The right side of the brain was seen as the inferior and thought to be
prominent in women, savages, children, criminals, and the insane. A
prime example of this in fictional literature can be seen in Robert Louis Stevenson's Strange Case of Dr. Jekyll and Mr. Hyde.
Evolutionary advantage
The
widespread lateralization of many vertebrate animals indicates an
evolutionary advantage associated with the specialization of each
hemisphere.
History
Broca
One of the first indications of brain function lateralization resulted from the research of French physician Pierre Paul Broca, in 1861. His research involved the male patient nicknamed "Tan", who suffered a speech deficit (aphasia); "tan" was one of the few words he could articulate, hence his nickname. In Tan's autopsy, Broca determined he had a syphilitic lesion in the left cerebral hemisphere. This left frontal lobe brain area (Broca's area)
is an important speech production region. The motor aspects of speech
production deficits caused by damage to Broca's area are known as expressive aphasia. In clinical assessment of this aphasia, it is noted that the patient cannot clearly articulate the language being employed.
Wernicke
German physician Karl Wernicke
continued in the vein of Broca's research by studying language deficits
unlike expressive aphasia. Wernicke noted that not every deficit was in
speech production; some were linguistic. He found that damage to the
left posterior, superior temporalgyrus (Wernicke's area) caused language comprehension deficits rather than speech production deficits, a syndrome known as receptive aphasia.
Imaging
These
seminal works on hemispheric specialization were done on patients or
postmortem brains, raising questions about the potential impact of
pathology on the research findings. New methods permit the in vivo comparison of the hemispheres in healthy subjects. Particularly, magnetic resonance imaging (MRI) and positron emission tomography (PET) are important because of their high spatial resolution and ability to image subcortical brain structures.
Movement and sensation
In the 1940s, neurosurgeon Wilder Penfield and his neurologist colleague Herbert Jasper developed a technique of brain mapping to help reduce side effects caused by surgery to treat epilepsy. They stimulated motor and somatosensory cortices
of the brain with small electrical currents to activate discrete brain
regions. They found that stimulation of one hemisphere's motor cortex
produces muscle contraction on the opposite side of the body. Furthermore, the functional map of the motor and sensory cortices is fairly consistent from person to person; Penfield and Jasper's famous pictures of the motor and sensory homunculi were the result.
Split-brain patients
Research by Michael Gazzaniga and Roger Wolcott Sperry in the 1960s on split-brain patients led to an even greater understanding of functional laterality. Split-brain patients are patients who have undergone corpus callosotomy (usually as a treatment for severe epilepsy), a severing of a large part of the corpus callosum.
The corpus callosum connects the two hemispheres of the brain and
allows them to communicate. When these connections are cut, the two
halves of the brain have a reduced capacity to communicate with each
other. This led to many interesting behavioral
phenomena that allowed Gazzaniga and Sperry to study the contributions
of each hemisphere to various cognitive and perceptual processes. One of
their main findings was that the right hemisphere was capable of
rudimentary language processing, but often has no lexical or grammatical
abilities. Eran Zaidel also studied such patients and found some evidence for the right hemisphere having at least some syntactic ability.
Language is primarily localized in the left hemisphere. One of
the experiments carried out by Gazzaniga involved a split-brain male
patient sitting in front of a computer screen while having words and
images presented on either side of the screen and the visual stimuli
would go to either the right or left visual field, and thus the left or
right brain, respectively. It was observed that if the patient was
presented with an image to his left visual field (right brain), he would
report not seeing anything. If he was able to feel around for certain
objects, he could accurately pick out the correct object, despite not
having the ability to verbalize what he saw. This led to confirmation
that the left brain is localized for language whereas the right brain
does not have this capability, and when the corpus callosum is cut, the
two hemispheres cannot communicate in order for situation-pertinent
speech to be produced.
In animal communication, an alarm signal is an antipredator adaptation in the form of signals emitted by social animals in response to danger. Many primates and birds have elaborate alarm calls for warning conspecifics of approaching predators. For example, the alarm call of the blackbird is a familiar sound in many gardens. Other animals, like fish and insects, may use non-auditory signals, such as chemical messages.
Visual signs such as the white tail flashes of many deer have been
suggested as alarm signals; they are less likely to be received by
conspecifics, so have tended to be treated as a signal to the predator instead.
Different calls may be used for predators on the ground or from
the air. Often, the animals can tell which member of the group is making
the call, so that they can disregard those of little reliability.
Evidently, alarm signals promote survival by allowing the
receivers of the alarm to escape from the source of peril; this can
evolve by kin selection,
assuming the receivers are related to the signaller. However, alarm
calls can increase individual fitness, for example by informing the
predator it has been detected.
Alarm calls are often high-frequency sounds because these sounds are harder to localize.
Selective advantage
This cost/benefit tradeoff of alarm calling behaviour has sparked many interest debates among evolutionary biologists
seeking to explain the occurrence of such apparently "self-sacrificing"
behaviour. The central question is this: "If the ultimate purpose of
any animal behaviour is to maximize the chances that an organism's own
genes are passed on, with maximum fruitfulness, to future generations,
why would an individual deliberately risk destroying itself (their
entire genome) for the sake of saving others (other genomes)?".
Some scientists have used the evidence of alarm-calling behaviour
to challenge the theory that "evolution works only/primarily at the
level of the gene and of the gene's "interest" in passing itself along to future generations." If alarm-calling is truly an example of altruism, then our understanding of natural selection becomes more complicated than simply "survival of the fittest gene".
Other researchers, generally those who support the selfish gene theory, question the authenticity of this "altruistic" behaviour. For instance, it has been observed that vervets
sometimes emit calls in the presence of a predator, and sometimes do
not. Studies show that these vervets may call more often when they are
surrounded by their own offspring and by other relatives who share many
of their genes. Other researchers have shown that some forms of alarm calling, for example, "aerial predator whistles" produced by Belding's ground squirrels,
do not increase the chances that a caller will get eaten by a predator;
the alarm call is advantageous to both caller and recipient by
frightening and warding off the predator.
Another theory suggests that alarm signals function to attract
further predators, which fight over the prey organism, giving it a
better chance of escape.
Others still suggest they are a deterrent to predators, communicating
the animals alertness to the predator. One such case is the eastern swamphen (Porphyrio porphyrio), which gives conspicuous visual tail flicks.
Considerable research effort continues to be directed toward the
purpose and ramifications of alarm-calling behaviour, because, to the
extent that this research has the ability to comment on the occurrence
or non-occurrence of altruistic behaviour, we can apply these findings
to our understanding of altruism in human behaviour.
Vervet monkeys
are the typical example of both animal alarm calls and of semantic
capacity in non-human animals. They have three distinct calls for leopards, snakes, and eagles,
and research shows that each call elicits different responses. When
vervets are on the ground they respond to the eagle alarm call by
looking up and running to cover, to leopard alarm calls primarily by
looking up and running into a tree, and to the snake alarm call
primarily by looking down. When in trees vervets responded to the eagle
alarm call by looking up and down and running out of trees, to the
leopard alarm call by running higher in the tree and looking both up and
down, and to the snake alarm call by looking primarily down.
Campbell's mona monkeys
also generate alarm calls, but in a different way than vervet monkeys.
Instead of having discrete calls for each predator, Campbell monkeys
have two distinct types of calls which contain different calls which
consist in an acoustic continuum of affixes which change meaning. It has
been suggested that this is a homology to human morphology. Similarly, the cotton-top tamarin is able to use a limited vocal range of alarm calls to distinguish between aerial and land predators.
Both the Campbell monkey and the cotton-top tamarin have demonstrated
abilities similar to vervet monkeys' ability to distinguish likely
direction of predation and appropriate responses.
That these three species use vocalizations to warn others of danger has been called by some proof of proto-language in primates.
However, there is some evidence that this behavior does not refer to
the predators themselves but to threat, distinguishing calls from words.
Another species that exhibits alarm calls is the Barbary macaque. Barbary macaque mothers are able to recognize their own offspring's calls and behave accordingly.
Not all scholars of animal communication accept the
interpretation of alarm signals in monkeys as having semantic properties
or transmitting "information". Prominent spokespersons for this
opposing view are Michael Owren and Drew Rendall, whose work on this topic has been widely cited and debated.
The alternative to the semantic interpretation of monkey alarm signals
as suggested in the cited works is that animal communication is
primarily a matter of influence rather than information, and that vocal
alarm signals are essentially emotional expressions influencing the
animals that hear them. In this view monkeys do not designate predators
by naming them, but may react with different degrees of vocal alarm
depending on the nature of the predator and its nearness on detection,
as well as by producing different types of vocalization under the
influence of the monkey's state and movement during the different types
of escape required by different predators. Other monkeys may learn to
use these emotional cues along with the escape behavior of the alarm
signaler to help make a good decision about the best escape route for
themselves, without there having been any naming of predators.
False alarm calls
Deceptive vocalizations are given by male barn swallows
Deceptive alarm calls are used by male swallows (Hirundo rustica). Males give these false alarm calls when females leave the nest area during the mating season, and are thus able to disrupt extra-pair copulations. As this is likely to be costly to females, it can be seen as an example of sexual conflict.
Counterfeit alarm calls are also used by thrushes to avoid intraspecific competition.
By sounding a bogus alarm call normally used to warn of aerial
predators, they can frighten other birds away, allowing them to eat
undisturbed.
Vervets
seem to be able to understand the referent of alarm calls instead of
merely the acoustic properties, and if another species' specific alarm
call (terrestrial or aerial predator, for instance) is used incorrectly
with too high of a regularity, the vervet will learn to ignore the
analogous vervet call as well.
Alarm pheromones
Alarm signals need not be communicated only by auditory means. For example, many animals may use chemosensory alarm signals, communicated by chemicals known as pheromones. Minnows and catfish release alarm pheromones (Schreckstoff) when injured, which cause nearby fish to hide in dense schools near the bottom.
Animals are not the only organism to communicate threats to
conspecifics either; some plants are able to perform a similar trick. Lima beans release volatile chemical signals that are received by nearby plants of the same species when infested with spider mites.
This 'message' allows the recipients to prepare themselves by
activating defense genes, making them less vulnerable to attack, and
also attracting another mite species that is a predator of spider mites (indirect defence).
Although it is conceivable that other plants are only intercepting a
message primarily functioning to attract "bodyguards", some plants
spread this signal on to others themselves, suggesting an indirect
benefit from increased inclusive fitness.
False chemical alarm signals are also employed. The aphid Myzus persicae is repelled by the wild potato Solanum berthaultii which releases a chemical from its leaves that acts as an allomone to disrupt aphid attacks.
By stotting (also called pronking), a springbok (Antidorcas marsupialis) signals honestly that it is young, fit, and not worth chasing to predators such as cheetahs.
Signals are given in contexts such as mate selection by females, which subjects the advertising
males' signals to selective pressure. Signals thus evolve because they
modify the behaviour of the receiver to benefit the signaller. Signals
may be honest, conveying information which usefully increases the
fitness of the receiver, or dishonest. An individual can cheat by giving
a dishonest signal, which might briefly benefit that signaller, at the
risk of undermining the signalling system for the whole population.
The question of whether selection of signals works at the level
of the individual organism or gene, or at the level of the group, has
been debated by biologists such as Richard Dawkins, arguing that individuals evolve to signal and to receive signals better, including resisting manipulation. Amotz Zahavi suggested that cheating could be controlled by the handicap principle, where the best horse in a handicap race
is the one carrying the largest handicap weight. According to Zahavi's
theory, signallers such as male peacocks have 'tails' that are genuinely
handicaps, being costly to produce. The system is evolutionarily stable
as the large showy tails are honest signals. Biologists have attempted
to verify the handicap principle, but with inconsistent results. The
mathematical biologist Ronald Fisher analysed the contribution that having two copies of each gene (diploidy) would make to honest signalling, demonstrating that a runaway effect could occur in sexual selection. The evolutionary equilibrium depends sensitively on the balance of costs and benefits.
The same mechanisms can be expected in humans, where researchers
have studied behaviours including risk taking by young men, hunting of
large game animals, and costly religious rituals, finding that these
appear to qualify as costly honest signals.
Sexual selection
When animals choose mates, traits such as signalling are subject to evolutionary pressure. For example, the male gray tree frog, Hyla versicolor,
produces a call to attract females. Once a female chooses a mate, this
selects for a specific style of male calling, thus propagating a
specific signalling ability. The signal can be the call itself, the
intensity of a call, its variation style, its repetition rate, and so
on. Various hypotheses seek to explain why females would select for one
call over the other. The sensory exploitation hypothesis proposes that
pre-existing preferences in female receivers can drive the evolution of
signal innovation in male senders, in a similar way to the hidden
preference hypothesis which proposes that successful calls are better
able to match some 'hidden preference' in the female. Signallers have sometimes evolved multiple sexual ornaments, and receivers have sometimes evolved multiple trait preferences.
Honest signals
Eurasian jay, Garrulus glandarius, gives honest signals—loud alarm calls—from its tree perch when it sees a predator.
In biology, signals are traits, including structures and behaviours,
that have evolved specifically because they change the behaviour of
receivers in ways that benefit the signaller.
Traits or actions that benefit the receiver exclusively are called
cues. When an alert bird deliberately gives a warning call to a
stalking predator and the predator gives up the hunt, the sound is a
signal. When a foraging bird inadvertently makes a rustling sound in
the leaves that attracts predators and increases the risk of predation,
the sound is a 'cue'.
Signalling systems are shaped by mutual interests between signallers and receivers. An alert bird such as a Eurasian jay
warning off a stalking predator is communicating something useful to
the predator: that it has been detected by the prey; it might as well
quit wasting its time stalking this alerted prey, which it is unlikely
to catch. When the predator gives up, the signaller can get back to
other tasks such as feeding. Once the stalking predator is detected,
the signalling prey and receiving predator thus have a mutual interest
in terminating the hunt.
Within species, mutual interests increase with kinship.
Kinship is central to models of signalling between relatives, for
instance when broods of nestling birds beg and compete for food from
their parents.
The term honesty in animal communication
is controversial because in non-technical usage it implies intent, to
discriminate deception from honesty in human interactions.
However, biologists use the phrase "honest signals" in a direct,
statistical sense. Biological signals, like warning calls or
resplendent tail feathers, are honest if they truly convey useful
information to the receiver. That is, the signal trait conveys to the receiver the presence of an otherwise unobservable factor.
Honest biological signals do not need to be perfectly informative,
reducing uncertainty to zero; all they need to be useful is to be
correct "on average", so that certain behavioural responses to the
signal are advantageous, statistically, compared to the behaviour that
would occur in absence of the signal. Ultimately the value of the signalled information depends on the extent to which it allows the receiver to increase its fitness. Hence, "honest" signals are evolutionarily stable.
One class of honest signal is the aposematic warning signal, generally visual, given by poisonous or dangerous animals such as wasps, poison dart frogs, and pufferfish.
Warning signals are honest indications of noxious prey, because
conspicuousness evolves in tandem with noxiousness. Thus, the brighter
and more conspicuous the organism, the more toxic it usually is. The most common and effective colours are red, yellow, black and white.
Dishonest signals
Male fiddler crab signals with its enlarged fighting claw, but weak regrown claws may be dishonest signals.
Because there are both mutual and conflicting interests in most
animal signalling systems, a central problem in signalling theory is
dishonesty or cheating.
For example, if foraging birds are safer when they give a warning
call, cheats could give false alarms at random, just in case a predator
is nearby. But too much cheating could cause the signalling system to
collapse. Every dishonest signal weakens the integrity of the signalling
system, and so reduces the fitness of the group. An example of dishonest signalling comes from Fiddler crabs such as Uca lactea mjoebergi,
which have been shown to bluff (no conscious intention being implied)
about their fighting ability. When a claw is lost, a crab occasionally
regrows a weaker claw that nevertheless intimidates crabs with smaller
but stronger claws.
The proportion of dishonest signals is low enough for it not to be
worthwhile for crabs to test the honesty of every signal through combat.
Richard Dawkins and John Krebs in 1978 considered whether individuals of the same species would act as if attempting to deceive each other. They applied a "selfish gene" view of evolution to animals' threat displays to see if it would be in their genes' interests to give dishonest signals. They criticised previous ethologists, such as Nikolaas Tinbergen and Desmond Morris for suggesting that such displays were "for the good of the species". They argued that such communication ought to be viewed as an evolutionary arms race
in which signallers evolve to become better at manipulating receivers,
while receivers evolve to become more resistant to manipulation. The game theoretical model of the war of attrition similarly suggests that threat displays ought not to convey any reliable information about intentions.
Sports handicapping metaphor
The best horses in a handicap race carry the largest weights, so the size of the handicap is a measure of the animal's quality.
In 1975, Amotz Zahavi proposed a verbal model for how signal costs could constrain cheating and stabilize an "honest" correlation between observed signals and unobservable qualities, based on an analogy to sports handicapping systems. He called this idea the handicap principle.
The purpose of a sports handicapping system is to reduce disparities in
performance, making the contest more competitive. In a handicap race, intrinsically faster horses are given heavier weights to carry under their saddles. Similarly, in amateur golf,
better golfers have fewer strokes subtracted from their raw scores.
This creates correlations between the handicap and unhandicapped
performance, if the handicaps work as they are supposed to, between the
handicap imposed and the corresponding horse's handicapped performance.
If you knew nothing about two race horses or two amateur golfers except
their handicaps, you could infer which is most likely to win: the horse
with the bigger weight handicap, and the golfer with the smaller stroke
handicap. By analogy, if peacock 'tails' (large tail covertfeathers)
act as a handicapping system, and a peahen knew nothing about two
peacocks but the sizes of their tails, she could "infer" that the
peacock with the bigger tail has greater unobservable intrinsic quality.
Display costs can include extrinsic social costs, in the form of
testing and punishment by rivals, as well as intrinsic production costs. Another example given in textbooks is the extinct Irish elk, Megaloceros giganteus. The male Irish elk's enormous antlers
could perhaps have evolved as displays of ability to overcome handicap,
though biologists point out that if the handicap is inherited, its
genes ought to be selected against.
Peacock signals reproductive fitness with its large colourful tail, possibly because it is a handicap.
The essential idea here is intuitive and probably qualifies as folk wisdom. It was articulated by Kurt Vonnegut in his 1961 short story Harrison Bergeron. In Vonnegut’s futuristic dystopia,
the Handicapper General uses a variety of handicapping mechanisms to
reduce inequalities in performance. A spectator at a ballet comments:
"it was easy to see that she was the strongest and most graceful of all
dancers, for her handicap bags were as big as those worn by two hundred
pound men." Zahavi interpreted this analogy to mean that higher quality
peacocks with bigger tails are signalling their ability to "waste" more
of some resource by trading it off for a bigger tail. This resonates
with Thorstein Veblen's idea that conspicuous consumption and extravagant status symbols can signal wealth.
The enormous antlers of the extinct Irish elk, Megaloceros giganteus may have evolved as displays of ability to overcome handicap.
Zahavi’s conclusions rest on his verbal interpretation of a metaphor,
and initially the handicap principle was not well received by
evolutionary biologists. However, in 1984, Nur and Hasson used life history theory
to show how differences in signalling costs, in the form of
survival-reproduction tradeoffs, could stabilize a signalling system
roughly as Zahavi imagined. Genetic models also suggested this was
possible.
In 1990 Alan Grafen showed that a handicap-like signalling system was
evolutionarily stable if higher quality signallers paid lower marginal
survival costs for their signals.
In 1982, W.D. Hamilton proposed a specific but widely applicable handicap mechanism, parasite-mediated sexual selection. He argued that in the never-ending co-evolutionary race between hosts and their parasites, sexually selected signals indicate health. This idea was tested in 1994 in barn swallows,
a species where males have long tail streamers. Møller found that the
males with longer tails, and their offspring, did have fewer
bloodsucking mites, whereas fostered young did not. The effect was
therefore genetic, confirming Hamilton's theory.
Another example is Lozano's hypothesis that carotenoids have dual but mutually incompatible roles in immune function and signalling. Given that animals cannot synthesize carotenoids de novo,
these must be obtained from food. The hypothesis states that animals
with carotenoid-depended sexual signals are demonstrating their ability
to "waste" carotenoids on sexual signals at the expense of their immune
system.
The handicap principle has proven hard to test empirically,
partly because of inconsistent interpretations of Zahavi’s metaphor and
Grafen’s marginal fitness model, and partly because of conflicting
empirical results: in some studies individuals with bigger signals seem
to pay higher costs, in other studies they seem to be paying lower
costs. A possible explanation for the inconsistent empirical results is given in a series of papers by Getty,
who shows that Grafen’s proof of the handicap principle is based on the
critical simplifying assumption that signallers trade off costs for
benefits in an additive fashion, the way humans invest money to increase
income in the same currency. But the assumption that costs and benefits trade off in an additive fashion is true only on a logarithmic scale;
for the survival cost – reproduction benefit tradeoff is assumed to
mediate the evolution of sexually selected signals. Fitness depends on
producing offspring, which is a multiplicative function of reproductive
success given an individual is still alive times the probability of
still being alive, given investment in signals.
Costly signalling and Fisherian diploid dynamics
The
effort to discover how costs can constrain an "honest" correlation
between observable signals and unobservable qualities within signallers
is built on strategic models of signalling games, with many simplifying
assumptions. These models are most often applied to sexually selected signalling in diploid animals, but they rarely incorporate a fact about diploid sexual reproduction noted by the mathematical biologist Ronald Fisher
in the early 20th century: if there are "preference genes" correlated
with choosiness in females as well as "signal genes" correlated with
display traits in males, choosier females should tend to mate with
showier males. Over generations, showier sons should also carry genes
associated with choosier daughters, and choosier daughters should also
carry genes associated with showier sons. This can cause the
evolutionary dynamic known as Fisherian runaway, in which males become ever showier. Russell Lande explored this with a quantitative genetic model,
showing that Fisherian diploid dynamics are sensitive to signalling and
search costs. Other models incorporate both costly signalling and
Fisherian runaway. These models show that if fitness depends on both survival and reproduction, having sexy sons
and choosy daughters (in the stereotypical model) can be adaptive,
increasing fitness just as much as having healthy sons and daughters.
Examples
One theory is that autumnal colours are a signal from trees to aphids of powerful chemical defences.
Sam Brown and W. D. Hamilton and Marco Archetti proposed that autumn leaf colour is a signal from trees to aphids
and other pest species that migrate in autumn to the trees. In their
theory, bright autumn coloration with pinks and yellows is costly to
trees because pigments require energy to synthesize, but the investment
may help them to reduce their parasite load.
Stotting, for example in Thomson's Gazelle,
is cited as an example of signalling: the gazelles jump close to a
predator instead of escaping, in what could be a signal of strength.
Human honest signals
Human
behaviour may also provide examples of costly signals. In general,
these signals provide information about a person’s phenotypic quality or
cooperative tendencies. Evidence for costly signalling has been found
in many areas of human interaction including risk taking, hunting, and
religion.
Costly signalling in hunting
A male hunter and a female gatherer of the Kali'na people of Guyana, drawn by Pierre Barrère in 1743. Generous sharing by male hunters may serve as a "costly signal", helping them to acquire mates.
Large game hunting has been studied extensively as a signal of men’s
willingness to take physical risks, as well as showcase strength and
coordination. Costly signalling theory is a useful tool for understanding food sharing among hunter gatherers because it can be applied to situations in which delayed reciprocity is not a viable explanation.
Instances that are particularly inconsistent with the delayed
reciprocity hypothesis are those in which a hunter shares his kill
indiscriminately with all members of a large group.
In these situations, the individuals sharing meat have no control over
whether or not their generosity will be reciprocated, and free riding
becomes an attractive strategy for those receiving meat. Free riders
are people who reap the benefits of group-living without contributing to
its maintenance. Fortunately, costly signalling theory can fill some of the gaps left by the delayed reciprocity hypothesis. Hawkes has suggested that men target large game and publicly share meat to draw social attention or to show off.
Such display and the resulting favorable attention can improve a
hunter’s reputation by providing information about his phenotypic
quality. High quality signallers are more successful in acquiring mates
and allies. Thus, costly signalling theory can explain apparently
wasteful and altruistic behaviour.
In order to be effective, costly signals must fulfill specific criteria.
Firstly, signallers must incur different levels of cost and benefit for
signalling behaviour. Secondly, costs and benefits must reflect the
signallers’ phenotypic
quality. Thirdly, the information provided by a signal should be
directed at and accessible to an audience. A receiver can be anyone who
stands to benefit from information the signaller is sending, such as
potential mates, allies, or competitors. Honesty is guaranteed when only
individuals of high quality can pay the (high) costs of signalling.
Hence, costly signals make it impossible for low-quality individuals to fake a signal and fool a receiver.
Bliege Bird et al. observed turtle hunting and spear fishing patterns in a Meriam community in the Torres Strait
of Australia, publishing their findings in 2001. Here, only some Meriam
men were able to accumulate high caloric gains for the amount of time
spent turtle hunting or spear fishing (reaching a threshold measured in
kcal/h). Since a daily catch of fish is carried home by hand and turtles
are frequently served at large feasts, members of the community know
which men most reliably brought them turtle meat and fish. Thus, turtle
hunting qualifies as a costly signal. Furthermore, turtle hunting and
spear fishing are actually less productive (in kcal/h) than foraging for
shellfish, where success depends only on the amount of time dedicated
to searching, so shellfish foraging is a poor signal of skill or
strength. This suggests that energetic gains are not the primary reason
men take part in turtle hunting and spear fishing.
A follow-up study found that successful Meriam hunters do experience
greater social benefits and reproductive success than less skilled
hunters.
The Hadza people of Tanzania also share food, possibly to gain in reputation.
Hunters cannot be sharing meat mainly to provision their families or to
gain reciprocal benefits, as teenage boys often give away their meat
even though they do not yet have wives or children, so costly signalling
of their qualities is the likely explanation.
These qualities include good eyesight, coordination, strength,
knowledge, endurance, or bravery. Hadza hunters more often pair with
highly fertile, hard-working wives than non-hunters.
A woman benefits from mating with a man who possesses such qualities as
her children will most likely inherit qualities that increase fitness
and survivorship. She may also benefit from her husband’s high social
status. Thus, hunting is an honest and costly signal of phenotypic
quality.
Among the men of Ifaluk atoll, costly signalling theory can also explain why men torch fish.
Torch fishing is a ritualized method of fishing on Ifaluk whereby men
use torches made from dried coconut fronds to catch large dog-toothed
tuna. Preparation for torch fishing requires significant time
investments and involves a great deal of organization. Due to the time
and energetic costs of preparation, torch fishing results in net caloric
losses for fishers. Therefore, torch fishing is a handicap that serves
to signal men’s productivity.
Torch fishing is the most advertised fishing occupation on Ifaluk.
Women and others usually spend time observing the canoes as they sail
beyond the reef. Also, local rituals help to broadcast information about
which fishers are successful and enhance fishers’ reputations during
the torch fishing season. Several ritual behavioural and dietary
constraints clearly distinguish torch fishers from other men. First,
males are only permitted to torch fish if they participated on the first
day of the fishing season. The community is well informed as to who
participates on this day, and can easily identify the torch fishers.
Second, torch fishers receive all of their meals at the canoe house and
are prohibited from eating certain foods. People frequently discuss the
qualities of torch fishermen. On Ifaluk, women claim that they are
looking for hard-working mates. With the distinct sexual division of labor on Ifaluk, industriousness is a highly valued characteristic in males.
Torch fishing thus provides women with reliable information on the work
ethic of prospective mates, which makes it an honest costly signal.
In many human cases, a strong reputation built through costly
signalling enhances a man’s social status over the statuses of men who
signal less successfully. Among northern Kalahari foraging groups, traditional hunters usually capture a maximum of two or three antelopes per year. It was said of a particularly successful hunter:
"It was said of him that he never returned from a hunt without
having killed at least a wildebeest, if not something larger. Hence the
people connected with him ate a great deal of meat and his popularity
grew."
Although this hunter was sharing meat, he was not doing so in the framework of reciprocity. The general model of costly signalling is not reciprocal; rather, individuals who share acquire more mates and allies.
Costly signalling applies to situations in Kalahari foraging groups
where giving often goes to recipients who have little to offer in
return. A young hunter is motivated to impress community members with
daughters so that he can obtain his first wife. Older hunters may wish
to attract women interested in an extramarital relationship, or to be a co-wife.
In these northern Kalahari groups, the killing of a large animal
indicates a man who has mastered the art of hunting and can support a
family.
Generally, many women seek a man who is a good hunter, has an agreeable
character, is generous, and has advantageous social ties.
Since hunting ability is a prerequisite for marriage, men who are good
hunters enter the marriage market earliest. Costly signalling theory
explains seemingly wasteful foraging displays.
Physical risks as a costly signal
Young men may take part in risky sports like motorcycle racing to signal their strength and skill.
Costly signalling can be applied to situations involving physical strain and risk of physical injury or death.
Research on physical risk taking is important because information
regarding why people, especially young men, take part in high risk
activities can help in the development of prevention programs. Reckless driving is a lethal problem among young men in western societies.
A male who takes a physical risk is sending the message that he has
enough strength and skill to survive extremely dangerous activities.
This signal is directed at peers and potential mates. When those peers are criminals or gang members, sociologists Diego Gambetta and James Densley find that risk-taking signals can help expedite acceptance into the group.
In a study of risk taking, some types of risk, such as physical
or heroic risk for others' benefit, are viewed more favorably than other
types of risk, such as taking drugs. Males and females valued different
degrees of heroic risk for mates and same-sex friends. Males valued
heroic risk taking by male friends, but preferred less of it in female
mates. Females valued heroic risk taking in male mates and less of it in
female friends. Females may be attracted to males inclined to
physically defend them and their children. Males may prefer heroic risk
taking by male friends as they could be good allies.
In western societies, voluntary blood donation is a common, yet less extreme, form of risk taking. Costs associated with these donations include pain and risk of infection.
If blood donation is an opportunity to send costly signals, then donors
will be perceived by others as generous and physically healthy.
In a survey, both donors and non-donors expressed perceptions of the
health, generosity, and ability of blood donors to operate in stressful
situations.
Religion as a costly signal
Religious rituals such as snake handling may be explainable as costly signals.
Costly religious rituals such as male circumcision, food and water deprivation, and snake handling
look paradoxical in evolutionary terms. Devout religious beliefs
wherein such traditions are practiced therefore appear maladaptive. Religion may have arisen to increase and maintain intragroup cooperation. Cooperation leads to altruistic behaviour, and costly signalling could explain this. All religions may involve costly and elaborate rituals, performed publicly, to demonstrate loyalty to the religious group.
In this way, group members increase their allegiance to the group by
signalling their investment in group interests. However, as group size
increases among humans, the threat of free riders grows. Costly signalling theory accounts for this by proposing that these religious rituals are costly enough to deter free riders.
Irons proposed that costly signalling theory could explain costly
religious behaviour. He argued that hard-to-fake religious displays
enhanced trust and solidarity in a community, producing emotional and
economic benefits. He showed that display signals among the YomutTurkmen of northern Iran helped to secure trade agreements. These "ostentatious" displays signalled commitment to Islam to strangers and group members.
Sosis demonstrated that people in religious communities are four times
more likely to live longer than their secular counterparts,
and that these longer lifespans were positively correlated with the
number of costly requirements demanded from religious community members. However, confounding variables may not have been excluded.
Wood found that religion offers a subjective feeling of well-being
within a community, where costly signalling protects against free riders
and helps to build self-control among committed members.
Iannaccone studied the effects of costly signals on religious
communities. In a self-reported survey, as the strictness of a church
increased, the attendance and contributions to that church increased
proportionally. In effect, people were more willing to participate in a
church that has more stringent demands on its members.
Despite this observation, costly donations and acts conducted in a
religious context does not itself establish that membership in these
clubs is actually worth the entry costs imposed.
Despite the experimental support for this hypothesis, it remains
controversial. A common critique is that devoutness is easy to fake,
such as simply by attending a religious service.
However, the hypothesis predicts that people are more likely to join
and contribute to a religious group when its rituals are costly.
Another critique specifically asks: why religion? There is no
evolutionary advantage to evolving religion over other signals of
commitment such as nationality, as Irons admits.
However, the reinforcement of religious rites as well as the intrinsic
reward and punishment system found in religion makes it an ideal
candidate for increasing intragroup cooperation. Finally, there is
insufficient evidence for increase in fitness as a result of religious
cooperation.
However, Sosis argues for benefits from religion itself, such as
increased longevity, improved health, assistance during crises, and
greater psychological well-being though both the supposed benefits from religion and the costly-signaling mechanism have been contested.
An endangered species recovery plan is a document describing the current status, threats and intended methods for increasing rare and endangered species population sizes. The U.S. Endangered Species Act of 1973 requires that all species considered endangered must have a plan implemented for their recovery,
but the format is also useful when considering the conservation of any
endangered species. Recovery plans act as a foundation from which you
can build a conservation effort and they can help to make conservation
more effective.
Background
The
United States congress said in 1973 that endangered species "are of
aesthetic, ecological, educational, historical, recreational, and
scientific value to the Nation and its people." They therefore set laws to protect endangered species. Section 4(f) of the United States Endangered Species Act
from 1973 directs the Secretary of the Interior and the Secretary of
Commerce to develop and implement recovery plans to promote the
conservation of endangered and threatened species. The Fish and Wildlife Service
and the National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA) National
Marine Fisheries Service are responsible for administering the act. The
recovery plan is a document which specifies what research and
management actions are necessary to support recovery, but does not
itself commit manpower or funds. Recovery plans are used in setting
funding priorities and provide direction to local, regional, and state
planning efforts. Recovery is when the threats to species survival are
neutralized and the species will be able to survive in the wild.
The International Union for Conservation of Nature
also create similar documents, Species Action Plans, which are used to
outline the conservation strategies of species, normally between set
dates.
These documents are used to clearly define the status and threats to
the species, and set aims for conservation so that parties involved can
work towards a common goal.
Endangered species
U.S. Endangered Species Act Categories
An endangered species is a species which is likely to become extinct. The U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service
has 17 categories of species status. These categories are used in the
documents produced for the U.S. Endangered species act. The categories
include:
Endangered (E) for species “in danger of extinction throughout all or a significant portion of its range”
Threatened (T) for species “likely to become endangered within the
foreseeable future throughout all or a significant portion of its range”
Candidate (C) for species currently under consideration
Species endangered due to “similarity of appearance” (SAE)
Species of concern (SC) for species that are considered “important to monitor” but have not been categorized as E,T or C
Delisted species removed from the list due to species recovery or extinction
IUCN red list categories
The IUCN also has categories that it uses to classify species, which are more widely used in conservation. These are:
Extinct (EX) – there are no individuals remaining of that species at all
Extinct in the wild (EW) – there are no individuals remaining of that species in the wild at all
Critically Endangered
(CR) – there is a very high risk that the species will soon go extinct
in the wild, for example because there is only a very small population
remaining
Endangered (EN) – there is a high risk of the species soon becoming extinct in the wild
Vulnerable (VU) – there is a high risk that the species will soon become endangered
Near threatened (NT) – there is a risk that the species will become threatened in the near future
Least concern (LC) – there is a low risk that the species will become threatened. This category is used for “widespread and abundant taxa”
Data Deficient (DD) – there is not enough data on the species to be able to make a reliable assessment on the status of the species
Not evaluated (NE) – the species has not yet been evaluated
Contents of a recovery plan
The recovery plan must contain at least:
A description of what is needed to return the species to a healthy state
Criteria for what this healthy state would be, so that the species can be removed from the endangered list when it is achieved
Estimates of how long the recovery will take and how much it will cost
A recovery plan often contains the following sections:
Background of the species - a description of the species, its
taxonomy, population structure and life history. This includes the
distribution, food sources, reproduction and abundance
Threats - the main reasons why the species is now at risk of extinction
Recovery strategy - details of how the species can be returned to a
healthy state, including the goals, timeline, methods and criteria for
delisting.
Adaptive management
When
recovery plans are carried out well, they do not simply act as stop
gaps to prevent extinction, but can restore species to a state of health
so they are self-sustaining. There is evidence to suggest that the best
plans are adaptive and dynamic, responding to changing conditions.
However, adaptive management requires the system to be constantly monitored so that changes are identified. Surprisingly this is frequently not done, even for species that have already been red listed.
The species must be monitored throughout the recovery period (and
beyond) to ensure that the plan is working as intended. The framework
for this monitoring should be planned before the start of the
implementation, and the details included in the recovery plan.
Information on how and when the data will be collected should be
supplied.
Habitat conservation plan
An
alternative method of conserving a species is to conserve the habitat
that the species is found in. In this process, there is no target
species for conservation, but rather the habitat as a whole is protected
and managed, often with a view to returning the habitat to a more
natural state. In theory, this method of conservation can be beneficial
because it allows for the entire ecosystem and the many species within
to benefit from conservation, rather than just the single target
species. The International Union for Conservation of Nature
suggest there is evidence that habitat based approaches do not have
enough focus on individual species to protect them sufficiently.
However much research now is turning towards area-based strategies in
preference to individual species approaches such as endangered species
recovery plans.