Capacitance is the ratio of the change in an electric charge in a system to the corresponding change in its electric potential. There are two closely related notions of capacitance: self capacitance and mutual capacitance. Any object that can be electrically charged exhibits self capacitance. A material with a large self capacitance holds more electric charge at a given voltage than one with low capacitance. The notion of mutual capacitance is particularly important for understanding the operations of the capacitor, one of the three elementary linear electronic components (along with resistors and inductors).
The capacitance is a function only of the geometry of the design
(e.g. area of the plates and the distance between them) and the permittivity of the dielectric
material between the plates of the capacitor. For many dielectric
materials, the permittivity and thus the capacitance, is independent of
the potential difference between the conductors and the total charge on
them.
The SI unit of capacitance is the farad (symbol: F), named after the English physicist Michael Faraday. A 1 farad capacitor, when charged with 1 coulomb of electrical charge, has a potential difference of 1 volt between its plates. The reciprocal of capacitance is called elastance.
Self-capacitance
In electrical circuits, the term capacitance is usually a shorthand for the mutual capacitance
between two adjacent conductors, such as the two plates of a capacitor.
However, for an isolated conductor, there also exists a property called
self-capacitance, which is the amount of electric charge that must be added to an isolated conductor to raise its electric potential by one unit (i.e. one volt, in most measurement systems).
The reference point for this potential is a theoretical hollow
conducting sphere, of infinite radius, with the conductor centered
inside this sphere.
Mathematically, the self-capacitance of a conductor is defined by
where
q is the charge held by the conductor,
is the electric potential,
σ is the surface charge density.
dS is an infinitesimal element of area,
r is the length from dS to a fixed point M within the plate
The inter-winding capacitance of a coil is sometimes called self-capacitance, but this is a different phenomenon. It is actually mutual capacitance between the individual turns of the coil and is a form of stray, or parasitic capacitance. This self-capacitance is an important consideration at high frequencies: It changes the impedance of the coil and gives rise to parallel resonance. In many applications this is an undesirable effect and sets an upper frequency limit for the correct operation of the circuit.
Mutual capacitance
A common form is a parallel-plate capacitor, which consists of two conductive plates insulated from each other, usually sandwiching a dielectric
material. In a parallel plate capacitor, capacitance is very nearly
proportional to the surface area of the conductor plates and inversely
proportional to the separation distance between the plates.
If the charges on the plates are +q and −q, and V gives the voltage between the plates, then the capacitance C is given by
The energy stored in a capacitor is found by integrating the work W
Capacitance matrix
The discussion above is limited to the case of two conducting plates, although of arbitrary size and shape.
The definition
does not apply when there are more than two charged plates, or when the
net charge on the two plates is non-zero. To handle this case, Maxwell
introduced his coefficients of potential. If three (nearly ideal) conductors are given charges , then the voltage at conductor 1 is given by
and similarly for the other voltages. Hermann von Helmholtz and Sir William Thomson showed that the coefficients of potential are symmetric, so that , etc. Thus the system can be described by a collection of coefficients known as the elastance matrix or reciprocal capacitance matrix, which is defined as:
From this, the mutual capacitance between two objects can be defined by solving for the total charge Q and using .
Since no actual device holds perfectly equal and opposite charges on
each of the two "plates", it is the mutual capacitance that is reported
on capacitors.
The collection of coefficients is known as the capacitance matrix, and is the inverse of the elastance matrix.
Capacitors
The capacitance of the majority of capacitors used in electronic
circuits is generally several orders of magnitude smaller than the farad. The most common subunits of capacitance in use today are the microfarad (µF), nanofarad (nF), picofarad (pF), and, in microcircuits, femtofarad (fF). However, specially made supercapacitors
can be much larger (as much as hundreds of farads), and parasitic
capacitive elements can be less than a femtofarad. In the past,
alternate subunits were used in historical electronic books; "mfd" and
"mf" for microfarad (µF); "mmfd", "mmf", "µµF" for picofarad (pF); but
are rarely used any more.
Capacitance can be calculated if the geometry of the conductors
and the dielectric properties of the insulator between the conductors
are known. A qualitative explanation for this can be given as follows.
Once a positive charge is put unto a conductor, this charge creates an
electrical field, repelling any other positive charge to be moved onto
the conductor; i.e., increasing the necessary voltage. But if nearby
there is another conductor with a negative charge on it, the electrical
field of the positive conductor repelling the second positive charge is
weakened (the second positive charge also feels the attracting force of
the negative charge). So due to the second conductor with a negative
charge, it becomes easier to put a positive charge on the already
positive charged first conductor, and vice versa; i.e., the necessary
voltage is lowered.
As a quantitative example consider the capacitance of a capacitor constructed of two parallel plates both of area A separated by a distance d. If d is sufficiently small with respect to the smallest chord of A, there holds, to a high level of accuracy:
where
C is the capacitance, in farads;
A is the area of overlap of the two plates, in square meters;
εr is the relative static permittivity (sometimes called the dielectric constant) of the material between the plates (for a vacuum, εr = 1);
d is the separation between the plates, in meters.
Capacitance is proportional to the area of overlap and inversely
proportional to the separation between conducting sheets. The closer the
sheets are to each other, the greater the capacitance.
The equation is a good approximation if d is small compared to
the other dimensions of the plates so that the electric field in the
capacitor area is uniform, and the so-called fringing field around the periphery provides only a small contribution to the capacitance. In CGS units the equation has the form
where C in this case has the units of length.
Combining the SI equation for capacitance with the above equation for
the energy stored in a capacitance, for a flat-plate capacitor the
energy stored is
where W is the energy, in joules; C is the capacitance, in farads; and V is the voltage, in volts.
Stray capacitance
Any two adjacent conductors can function as a capacitor, though the
capacitance is small unless the conductors are close together for long
distances or over a large area. This (often unwanted) capacitance is
called parasitic or "stray capacitance". Stray capacitance can allow
signals to leak between otherwise isolated circuits (an effect called crosstalk), and it can be a limiting factor for proper functioning of circuits at high frequency.
Stray capacitance between the input and output in amplifier circuits can be troublesome because it can form a path for feedback, which can cause instability and parasitic oscillation
in the amplifier. It is often convenient for analytical purposes to
replace this capacitance with a combination of one input-to-ground
capacitance and one output-to-ground capacitance; the original
configuration — including the input-to-output capacitance — is often
referred to as a pi-configuration. Miller's theorem can be used to
effect this replacement: it states that, if the gain ratio of two nodes
is 1/K, then an impedance of Z connecting the two nodes can be replaced with a Z/(1 − k) impedance between the first node and ground and a KZ/(K − 1)
impedance between the second node and ground. Since impedance varies
inversely with capacitance, the internode capacitance, C, is replaced by a capacitance of KC from input to ground and a capacitance of (K − 1)C/K
from output to ground. When the input-to-output gain is very large, the
equivalent input-to-ground impedance is very small while the
output-to-ground impedance is essentially equal to the original
(input-to-output) impedance.
Capacitance of conductors with simple shapes
Calculating the capacitance of a system amounts to solving the Laplace equation∇2φ = 0 with a constant potential φ
on the surface of the conductors. This is trivial in cases with high
symmetry. There is no solution in terms of elementary functions in more
complicated cases.
For two-dimensional situations analytic functions may be used to map different geometries to each other.
a:Radius d: Distance, d > 2a D = d/2a, D > 1 γ: Euler's constant
Sphere in front of wall
a: Radius d: Distance, d > a D = d/a
Sphere
a: Radius
Circular disc
a: Radius
Prolate ellipsoid
half-axes a>b=c
Thin straight wire, finite length
a: Wire radius ℓ: Length Λ: ln(ℓ/a)
Energy storage
The energy (measured in joules) stored in a capacitor is equal to the work required to push the charges into the capacitor, i.e. to charge it. Consider a capacitor of capacitance C, holding a charge +q on one plate and −q on the other. Moving a small element of charge dq from one plate to the other against the potential difference V = q/C requires the work dW:
where W is the work measured in joules, q is the charge measured in coulombs and C is the capacitance, measured in farads.
The energy stored in a capacitor is found by integrating this equation. Starting with an uncharged capacitance (q = 0) and moving charge from one plate to the other until the plates have charge +Q and −Q requires the work W:
Nanoscale systems
The capacitance of nanoscale dielectric capacitors such as quantum dots
may differ from conventional formulations of larger capacitors. In
particular, the electrostatic potential difference experienced by
electrons in conventional capacitors is spatially well-defined and fixed
by the shape and size of metallic electrodes in addition to the
statistically large number of electrons present in conventional
capacitors. In nanoscale capacitors, however, the electrostatic
potentials experienced by electrons are determined by the number and
locations of all electrons that contribute to the electronic properties
of the device. In such devices, the number of electrons may be very
small, however, the resulting spatial distribution of equipotential
surfaces within the device are exceedingly complex.
Single-electron devices
The
capacitance of a connected, or "closed", single-electron device is
twice the capacitance of an unconnected, or "open", single-electron
device.
This fact may be traced more fundamentally to the energy stored in the
single-electron device whose "direct polarization" interaction energy
may be equally divided into the interaction of the electron with the
polarized charge on the device itself due to the presence of the
electron and the amount of potential energy required to form the
polarized charge on the device (the interaction of charges in the
device's dielectric material with the potential due to the electron).
Few-electron devices
The derivation of a "quantum capacitance" of a few-electron device involves the thermodynamic chemical potential of an N-particle system given by
whose energy terms may be obtained as solutions of the Schrödinger equation. The definition of capacitance,
,
with the potential difference
may be applied to the device with the addition or removal of individual electrons,
and .
Then
is the "quantum capacitance" of the device.
This expression of "quantum capacitance" may be written as
which differs from the conventional expression described in the introduction where , the stored electrostatic potential energy,
by a factor of 1/2 with .
However, within the framework of purely classical electrostatic
interactions, the appearance of the factor of 1/2 is the result of
integration in the conventional formulation,
which is appropriate since for systems involving either many electrons or metallic electrodes, but in few-electron systems, .
The integral generally becomes a summation. One may trivially combine
the expressions of capacitance and electrostatic interaction energy,
and ,
respectively, to obtain,
which is similar to the quantum capacitance. A more rigorous derivation is reported in the literature. In particular, to circumvent the mathematical challenges of the spatially complex equipotential surfaces within the device, an average electrostatic potential experiences by each electron is utilized in the derivation.
The reason for apparent mathematical differences is understood more fundamentally as the potential energy, , of an isolated device (self-capacitance) is twice that stored in a "connected" device in the lower limit N=1. As N grows large, . Thus, the general expression of capacitance is
.
In nanoscale devices such as quantum dots, the "capacitor" is often
an isolated, or partially isolated, component within the device. The
primary differences between nanoscale capacitors and macroscopic
(conventional) capacitors are the number of excess electrons (charge
carriers, or electrons, that contribute to the device's electronic
behavior) and the shape and size of metallic electrodes. In nanoscale
devices, nanowires
consisting of metal atoms typically do not exhibit the same conductive
properties as their macroscopic, or bulk material, counterparts.
Capacitance in electronic and semiconductor devices
In
electronic and semiconductor devices, transient or frequency-dependent
current between terminals contains both conduction and displacement
components. Conduction current is related to moving charge carriers
(electrons, holes, ions, etc.), while displacement current is caused by
time-varying electric field. Carrier transport is affected by electric
field and by a number of physical phenomena - such as carrier drift and
diffusion, trapping, injection, contact-related effects, impact
ionization, etc. As a result, device admittance is frequency-dependent, and a simple electrostatic formula for capacitance is not applicable. A more general definition of capacitance, encompassing electrostatic formula, is:
where is the device admittance, and is the angular frequency.
In general case, capacitance is a function of frequency. At high
frequencies, capacitance approached a constant value, equal to
"geometric" capacitance, determined by the terminals' geometry and
dielectric content in the device.
A paper by Steven Laux
presents a review of numerical techniques for capacitance calculation.
In particular, capacitance can be calculated by a Fourier transform of a
transient current in response to a step-like voltage excitation:
Negative capacitance in semiconductor devices
Usually,
capacitance in semiconductor devices is positive. However, in some
devices and under certain conditions (temperature, applied voltages,
frequency, etc.), capacitance can become negative. Non-monotonic
behavior of the transient current in response to a step-like excitation
has been proposed as the mechanism of negative capacitance. Negative capacitance has been demonstrated and explored in many different types of semiconductor devices.
Daily load diagram; Blue shows real load usage and green shows ideal load.
Demand response is a change in the power consumption of an electric utility
customer to better match the demand for power with the supply. Until
recently electric energy could not be easily stored, so utilities have
traditionally matched demand and supply by throttling the production
rate of their power plants,
taking generating units on or off line, or importing power from other
utilities. There are limits to what can be achieved on the supply side,
because some generating units can take a long time to come up to full
power, some units may be very expensive to operate, and demand can at
times be greater than the capacity of all the available power plants put
together. Demand response seeks to adjust the demand for power instead
of adjusting the supply.
Utilities may signal demand requests to their customers in a
variety of ways, including simple off-peak metering, in which power is
cheaper at certain times of the day, and smart metering, in which explicit requests or changes in price can be communicated to customers.
The customer may adjust power demand by postponing some tasks
that require large amounts of electric power, or may decide to pay a
higher price for their electricity. Some customers may switch part of
their consumption to alternate sources, such as on-site diesel
generators.
In many respects, demand response can be put simply as a
technology-enabled economic rationing system for electric power supply.
In demand response, voluntary rationing is accomplished by price
incentives—offering lower net unit pricing in exchange for reduced power
consumption in peak periods. The direct implication is that users of
electric power capacity not reducing usage (load) during peak periods
will pay "surge" unit prices, whether directly, or factored into general
rates.
Involuntary rationing, if employed, would be accomplished via
rolling blackouts during peak load periods. Practically speaking, summer
heat waves and winter deep freezes might be characterized by planned
power outages for consumers and businesses if voluntary rationing via
incentives fail to reduce load adequately to match total power supply.
Background
According to the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, demand response (DR) is defined as: “Changes in electric usage by end-use customers from their normal
consumption patterns in response to changes in the price of electricity
over time, or to incentive payments designed to induce lower electricity
use at times of high wholesale market prices or when system reliability
is jeopardized.” DR includes all intentional modifications to
consumption patterns of electricity to induce customers that are
intended to alter the timing, level of instantaneous demand, or the
total electricity consumption.
It is expected that demand response programs will be designed to
decrease electricity consumption or shift it from on-peak to off-peak
periods depending on consumers’
preferences and lifestyles.
Demand Response can be defined as "a wide range of actions which can be
taken at the customer side of the electricity meter in response to
particular conditions within the electricity system (such as peak period
network congestion or high prices)".
Demand response is a reduction in demand designed to reduce peak demand
or avoid system emergencies. Hence, demand response can be a more
cost-effective alternative than adding generation capabilities to meet
the peak and or occasional demand spikes. The underlying objective of DR
is to actively engage customers in modifying their consumption in
response to pricing signals. The goal is to reflect supply expectations
through consumer price signals or controls and enable dynamic changes in consumption relative to price.
In electricity grids, DR is similar to dynamic demand
mechanisms to manage customer consumption of electricity in response to
supply conditions, for example, having electricity customers reduce
their consumption at critical times or in response to market prices.
The difference is that demand response mechanisms respond to explicit
requests to shut off, whereas dynamic demand devices passively shut off
when stress in the grid is sensed. Demand response can involve actually
curtailing power used or by starting on-site generation which may or may
not be connected in parallel with the grid. This is a quite different concept from energy efficiency,
which means using less power to perform the same tasks, on a continuous
basis or whenever that task is performed. At the same time, demand
response is a component of smart energy demand, which also includes
energy efficiency, home and building energy management, distributed renewable resources, and electric vehicle charging.
Current demand response schemes are implemented with large and
small commercial as well as residential customers, often through the use
of dedicated control systems to shed loads in response to a request by a
utility or market price conditions. Services (lights, machines, air
conditioning) are reduced according to a preplanned load prioritization
scheme during the critical time frames. An alternative to load shedding
is on-site generation of electricity to supplement the power grid.
Under conditions of tight electricity supply, demand response can
significantly decrease the peak price and, in general, electricity price
volatility.
Demand response is generally used to refer to mechanisms used to encourage consumers to reduce demand, thereby reducing the peak demand
for electricity. Since electrical generation and transmission systems
are generally sized to correspond to peak demand (plus margin for
forecasting error and unforeseen events), lowering peak demand reduces
overall plant and capital cost
requirements. Depending on the configuration of generation capacity,
however, demand response may also be used to increase demand (load) at
times of high production and low demand. Some systems may thereby
encourage energy storage to arbitrage between periods of low and high demand (or low and high prices).
There are three types of demand response - emergency demand
response, economic demand response and ancillary services demand
response.
Emergency demand response is employed to avoid involuntary service
interruptions during times of supply scarcity. Economic demand response
is employed to allow electricity customers to curtail their consumption
when the productivity or convenience of consuming that electricity is
worth less to them than paying for the electricity. Ancillary services
demand response consists of a number of specialty services that are
needed to ensure the secure operation of the transmission grid and which
have traditionally been provided by generators.
Smart grid application
Smart grid
applications improve the ability of electricity producers and consumers
to communicate with one another and make decisions about how and when
to produce and consume electrical power. This emerging technology will allow customers to shift from an
event-based demand response where the utility requests the shedding of
load, towards a more 24/7-based demand response where the customer sees
incentives for controlling load all the time. Although this
back-and-forth dialogue increases the opportunities for demand response,
customers are still largely influenced by economic incentives and are
reluctant to relinquish total control of their assets to utility
companies.
One advantage of a smart grid application is time-based pricing.
Customers who traditionally pay a fixed rate for consumed energy (kWh) and requested peak load
can set their threshold and adjust their usage to take advantage of
fluctuating prices. This may require the use of an energy management
system to control appliances and equipment and can involve economies of
scale. Another advantage, mainly for large customers with generation, is
being able to closely monitor, shift, and balance load in a way that
allows the customer to save peak load and not only save on kWh and
kW/month but be able to trade what they have saved in an energy market.
Again this involves sophisticated energy management systems, incentives,
and a viable trading market.
Smart grid applications increase the opportunities for demand response by providing real time data to producers and consumers, but the economic and environmental incentives remain the driving force behind the practice.
One of the most important means of demand response in the future
smart grids is electric vehicles. Aggregation of this new source of
energy, which is also a new source of uncertainty in the electrical
systems, is critical to preserving the stability and quality of smart
grids, consequently, the electric vehicle parking lots can be considered
a demand response aggregation entity.
Electricity pricing
Explanation
of demand response effects on a quantity (Q) -
price (P) graph. Under
inelastic demand (D1) extremely high
price (P1) may result on a strained
electricity market. If
demand response measures are employed the demand becomes more
elastic
(D2). A much lower price will result in the market (P2).
It is estimated that a 5% lowering of demand would result in a
50% price reduction during the peak hours of the California
electricity crisis in 2000/2001. The market also becomes more resilient to intentional withdrawal of offers from the supply side.
In most electric power systems, some or all consumers pay a fixed
price per unit of electricity independent of the cost of production at
the time of consumption. The consumer price may be established by the
government or a regulator, and typically represents an average cost per unit of production
over a given timeframe (for example, a year). Consumption therefore is
not sensitive to the cost of production in the short term (e.g. on an
hourly basis). In economic terms, consumers' usage of electricity is inelastic
in short time frames since the consumers do not face the actual price
of production; if consumers were to face the short run costs of
production they would be more inclined to change their use of
electricity in reaction to those price signals. A pure economist might
extrapolate the concept to hypothesize that consumers served under these
fixed-rate tariffs are endowed with theoretical "call options" on
electricity, though in reality, like any other business, the customer is
simply buying what is on offer at the agreed price.
A customer in a department store buying a $10 item at 9.00 am might
notice 10 sales staff on the floor but only one occupied serving him or
her, while at 3.00 pm the customer could buy the same $10 article and
notice all 10 sales staff occupied. In a similar manner, the department
store cost of sales at 9.00 am might therefore be 5-10 times that of
its cost of sales at 3.00 pm, but it would be far-fetched to claim that
the customer, by not paying significantly more for the article at 9.00
am than at 3.00 pm, had a 'call option' on the $10 article.
In virtually all power systems electricity is produced by
generators that are dispatched in merit order, i.e., generators with the
lowest marginal cost (lowest variable cost of production) are used
first, followed by the next cheapest, etc., until the instantaneous
electricity demand is satisfied. In most power systems the wholesale
price of electricity will be equal to the marginal cost of the highest
cost generator that is injecting energy, which will vary with the level
of demand. Thus the variation in pricing can be significant: for
example, in Ontario between August and September 2006, wholesale prices
(in Canadian Dollars) paid to producers ranged from a peak of $318 per
MW·h to a minimum of - (negative) $3.10 per MW·h.
It is not unusual for the price to vary by a factor of two to five due
to the daily demand cycle. A negative price indicates that producers
were being charged to provide electricity to the grid (and consumers
paying real-time pricing may have actually received a rebate for
consuming electricity during this period). This generally occurs at
night when demand falls to a level where all generators are operating at
their minimum output levels and some of them must be shut down. The
negative price is the inducement to bring about these shutdowns in a
least-cost manner.
Two Carnegie Mellon studies in 2006 looked at the importance of demand response for the electricity industry in general terms and with specific application of real-time pricing for consumers for the PJM Interconnection Regional Transmission authority.
The latter study found that even small shifts in peak demand would have
a large effect on savings to consumers and avoided costs for additional
peak capacity: a 1% shift in peak demand would result in savings of
3.9%, billions of dollars at the system level. An approximately 10%
reduction in peak demand (achievable depending on the elasticity of demand) would result in systems savings of between $8 to $28 billion.
In a discussion paper, Ahmad Faruqui, a principal with the Brattle Group,
estimates that a 5 percent reduction in US peak electricity demand
could produce approximately $35 billion in cost savings over a 20-year
period, exclusive of the cost of the metering and communications needed
to implement the dynamic pricing needed to achieve these reductions.
While the net benefits would be significantly less than the claimed $35
billion, they would still be quite substantial.
In Ontario, Canada, the Independent Electricity System Operator has
noted that in 2006, peak demand exceeded 25,000 megawatts during only 32
system hours (less than 0.4% of the time), while maximum demand during
the year was just over 27,000 megawatts. The ability to "shave" peak
demand based on reliable commitments would therefore allow the province
to reduce built capacity by approximately 2,000 megawatts.
In an electricity grid, electricity consumption and production must
balance at all times; any significant imbalance could cause grid
instability or severe voltage fluctuations, and cause failures within
the grid. Total generation capacity is therefore sized to correspond to
total peak demand with some margin of error and allowance for
contingencies (such as plants being off-line during peak demand
periods). Operators will generally plan to use the least expensive
generating capacity (in terms of marginal cost)
at any given period, and use additional capacity from more expensive
plants as demand increases. Demand response in most cases is targeted at
reducing peak demand to reduce the risk of potential disturbances,
avoid additional capital cost requirements for additional plants, and
avoid use of more expensive and/or less efficient operating plants.
Consumers of electricity will also pay higher prices if generation
capacity is used from a higher-cost source of power generation.
Demand response may also be used to increase demand during
periods of high supply and/or low demand. Some types of generating plant
must be run at close to full capacity (such as nuclear), while other
types may produce at negligible marginal cost (such as wind and solar).
Since there is usually limited capacity to store energy, demand response
may attempt to increase load during these periods to maintain grid
stability. For example, in the province of Ontario in September 2006,
there was a short period of time when electricity prices were negative
for certain users. Energy storage such as pumped-storage hydroelectricity
is a way to increase load during periods of low demand for use during
later periods. Use of demand response to increase load is less common,
but may be necessary or efficient in systems where there are large
amounts of generating capacity that cannot be easily cycled down.
Some grids may use pricing mechanisms that are not real-time, but
easier to implement (users pay higher prices during the day and lower
prices at night, for example) to provide some of the benefits of the
demand response mechanism with less demanding technological
requirements. In the UK, Economy 7
and similar schemes that attempt to shift demand associated with
electric heating to overnight off-peak periods have been in operation
since the 1970s. More recently, in 2006 Ontario began implementing a
"smart meter" program that implements "time-of-use" (TOU) pricing, which
tiers pricing according to on-peak, mid-peak and off-peak schedules.
During the winter, on-peak is defined as morning and early evening,
mid-peak as midday to late afternoon, and off-peak as nighttime; during
the summer, the on-peak and mid-peak periods are reversed, reflecting
air conditioning as the driver of summer demand. As of May 1, 2015, most
Ontario electrical utilities have completed converting all customers to
"smart meter" time-of-use billing with on-peak rates about 200% and
mid-peak rates about 150% of the off-peak rate per kWh.
Australia has national standards for Demand Response (AS/NZS 4755
series), which has been implemented nation wide by electricity
distributors for several decades, e.g. controlling storage water
heaters, air conditioners and pool pumps. In 2016, how to manage
electrical energy storage (e.g. batteries) has been added into the
series of standards.
Load shedding
Electrical generation and transmission systems may not always meet peak demand requirements— the greatest amount of electricity
required by all utility customers within a given region. In these
situations, overall demand must be lowered, either by turning off
service to some devices or cutting back the supply voltage (brownouts), in order to prevent uncontrolled service disruptions such as power outages (widespread blackouts) or equipment damage. Utilities may impose load shedding on service areas via rolling blackouts or by agreements with specific high-use industrial consumers to turn off equipment at times of system-wide peak demand.
Incentives to shed loads
Energy consumers need some incentive to respond to such a request from a demand response provider
(see list of providers below). Demand response incentives can be formal
or informal. For example, the utility might create a tariff-based
incentive by passing along short-term increases in the price of
electricity, or they might impose mandatory cutbacks during a heat wave
for selected high-volume users, who are compensated for their
participation. Other users may receive a rebate or other incentive based
on firm commitments to reduce power during periods of high demand, sometimes referred to as negawatts.
Commercial and industrial power users might impose load shedding
on themselves, without a request from the utility. Some businesses
generate their own power and wish to stay within their energy production
capacity to avoid buying power from the grid. Some utilities have
commercial tariff structures that set a customer's power costs for the
month based on the customer's moment of highest use, or peak demand.
This encourages users to flatten their demand for energy, known as energy demand management, which sometimes requires cutting back services temporarily.
Smart metering
has been implemented in some jurisdictions to provide real-time pricing
for all types of users, as opposed to fixed-rate pricing throughout the
demand period. In this application, users have a direct incentive to
reduce their use at high-demand, high-price periods. Many users may not
be able to effectively reduce their demand at various times, or the peak
prices may be lower than the level required to induce a change in
demand during short time periods (users have low price sensitivity, or elasticity of demand is low). Automated control systems exist, which, although effective, may be too expensive to be feasible for some applications.
Application for intermittent renewable distributed energy resources
The
modern power grid is making a transition from the traditional
vertically integrated utility structures to distributed systems as we
begin to integrate higher penetrations of renewable energy generation.
These sources of energy are often diffusely distributed and intermittent
by nature. These features introduce problems in grid stability and
efficiency which lead to limitations on the amount of these resources
which can be effectively added to the grid. In a traditional vertically
integrated grid, energy is provided by utility generators which are able
to respond to changes in demand. Generation output by renewable
resources is governed by environmental conditions and is generally not
able to respond to changes in demand. Responsive control over
non-critical loads which are connected to the grid has been shown to be
an effective strategy which is able to mitigate harmful fluctuations
introduced by these renewable resources.
In this way instead of letting the generation respond to changes in
demand, we have the demand respond to changes in generation. This is the
basis of demand response. In order to implement demand response
systems, we must be able to coordinate large numbers of distributed
resources through sensors, actuators, and communications protocols. To
be effective, the devices need to be economical, robust, and yet still
effective at managing their tasks of control. In addition, a strong
control mechanism must be created which is able to coordinate over large
networks of devices to manage and optimize these distributed systems
both from an economic standpoint and a security standpoint in grid
stabilization.
In addition, the increased presence of variable renewable generation drives a greater need for authorities to procure more ancillary services
(AS) for grid balance. One of these services is contingency reserve
(CR), which is used to regulate the grid frequency in contingencies.
Many independent system operators
(ISO) are structuring the rules of AS markets such that demand response
(DR) can participate alongside traditional supply-side resources. The
available capacity of the generators can be used more efficiently for
power production which they were designed for and not CR, thereby
cutting costs and reducing pollution. As the ratio of inverter-based
generation compared to conventional generation increases, the mechanical
inertia used to stabilize frequency decreases. When coupled with the
sensitivity of inverter-based generation to transient frequencies, the
provision of ancillary services from other sources than generators
becomes increasingly important.
Technologies for demand reduction
Technologies
are available, and more are under development, to automate the process
of demand response. Such technologies detect the need for load shedding, communicate the demand to participating users, automate load shedding, and verify compliance with demand-response programs. GridWise and EnergyWeb
are two major federal initiatives in the United States to develop these
technologies. Universities and private industry are also doing research
and development in this arena. Scalable and comprehensive software
solutions for DR enable business and industry growth.
Some utilities are considering and testing automated systems
connected to industrial, commercial and residential users that can
reduce consumption at times of peak demand, essentially delaying draw
marginally. Although the amount of demand delayed may be small, the
implications for the grid (including financial) may be substantial,
since system stability planning often involves building capacity for
extreme peak demand events, plus a margin of safety in reserve. Such
events may only occur a few times per year.
The process may involve turning down or off certain appliances or
sinks (and, when demand is unexpectedly low, potentially increasing
usage). For example, heating may be turned down or air conditioning or refrigeration
may be turned up (turning up to a higher temperature uses less
electricity), delaying slightly the draw until a peak in usage has
passed. In the city of Toronto, certain residential users can participate in a program (Peaksaver AC)
whereby the system operator can automatically control hot water heaters
or air conditioning during peak demand; the grid benefits by delaying
peak demand (allowing peaking plants time to cycle up or avoiding peak
events), and the participant benefits by delaying consumption until
after peak demand periods, when pricing should be lower. Although this
is an experimental program, at scale these solutions have the potential
to reduce peak demand considerably. The success of such programs depends
on the development of appropriate technology, a suitable pricing system
for electricity, and the cost of the underlying technology. Bonneville
Power experimented with direct-control technologies in Washington and
Oregon residences, and found that the avoided transmission investment
would justify the cost of the technology.
Other methods to implementing demand response approach the issue of subtly reducing duty cycles rather than implementing thermostat setbacks.
These can be implemented using customized building automation systems
programming, or through swarm-logic methods coordinating multiple loads
in a facility (e.g. Encycle's EnviroGrid controllers).
Similar approach can be implemented for managing air conditioning
peak demand in summer peak regions. Pre-cooling or maintaining slightly
higher thermostat setting can help with the peak demand reduction.
In 2008 it was announced that electric refrigerators will be sold in the UK sensing dynamic demand which will delay or advance the cooling cycle based on monitoring grid frequency but they are not readily available as of 2018.
Industrial customers
Industrial
customers are also providing demand response. Compared with commercial
and residential loads, industrial loads have the following advantages:
the magnitude of power consumption by an industrial manufacturing plant
and the change in power it can provide are generally very large;
besides, the industrial plants usually already have the infrastructures
for control, communication and market participation, which enables the
provision of demand response; moreover, some industrial plants such as
the aluminum smelter are able to offer fast and accurate adjustments in their power consumption. For example, Alcoa's Warrick Operation is participating in MISO as a qualified demand response resource, and the Trimet Aluminium uses its smelter as a short-term mega-battery. The selection of suitable industries for demand response provision is typically based on an assessment of the so-called value of lost load.
Short-term inconvenience for long-term benefits
Shedding
loads during peak demand is important because it reduces the need for
new power plants. To respond to high peak demand, utilities build very
capital-intensive power plants and lines. Peak demand happens just a few
times a year, so those assets run at a mere fraction of their capacity. Electric users pay for this idle capacity through the prices they pay
for electricity. According to the Demand Response Smart Grid Coalition,
10%–20% of electricity costs in the United States are due to peak demand
during only 100 hours of the year.
DR is a way for utilities to reduce the need for large capital
expenditures, and thus keep rates lower overall; however, there is an
economic limit to such reductions because consumers lose the productive
or convenience value of the electricity not consumed. Thus, it is
misleading to only look at the cost savings that demand response can
produce without also considering what the consumer gives up in the
process.
Importance for the operation of electricity markets
It is estimated that a 5% lowering of demand would have resulted in a 50% price reduction during the peak hours of the California electricity crisis
in 2000–2001. With consumers facing peak pricing and reducing their
demand, the market should become more resilient to intentional
withdrawal of offers from the supply side.
Residential and commercial electricity use often vary drastically
during the day, and demand response attempts to reduce the variability
based on pricing signals. There are three underlying tenets to these
programs:
Unused electrical production facilities represent a less efficient use of capital (little revenue is earned when not operating).
Electric systems and grids typically scale total potential
production to meet projected peak demand (with sufficient spare capacity
to deal with unanticipated events).
By "smoothing" demand to reduce peaks, less investment in
operational reserve will be required, and existing facilities will
operate more frequently.
In addition, significant peaks may only occur rarely, such as two or
three times per year, requiring significant capital investments to meet
infrequent events.
US Energy Policy Act regarding demand response
The United StatesEnergy Policy Act of 2005 has mandated the Secretary of Energy to submit to the US Congress
"a report that identifies and quantifies the national benefits of
demand response and makes a recommendation on achieving specific levels
of such benefits by January 1, 2007." Such a report was published in
February 2006.
The report estimates that in 2004 potential demand response capability equaled about 20,500 megawatts (MW),
3% of total U.S. peak demand, while actual delivered peak demand
reduction was about 9,000 MW (1.3% of peak), leaving ample margin for
improvement. It is further estimated that load management capability has
fallen by 32% since 1996. Factors affecting this trend include fewer
utilities offering load management services, declining enrollment in
existing programs, the changing role and responsibility of utilities,
and changing supply/demand balance.
To encourage the use and implementation of demand response in the United States, the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
(FERC) issued Order No. 745 in March 2011, which requires a certain
level of compensation for providers of economic demand response that
participate in wholesale power markets. The order is highly controversial and has been opposed by a number of energy economists, including Professor William W. Hogan at Harvard University's Kennedy School.
Professor Hogan asserts that the order overcompensates providers of
demand response, thereby encouraging the curtailment of electricity
whose economic value exceeds the cost of producing it. Professor Hogan
further asserts that Order No. 745 is anticompetitive and amounts to
“…an application of regulatory authority to enforce a buyer’s cartel.”
Several affected parties, including the State of California, have
filed suit in federal court challenging the legality of Order 745. A debate regarding the economic efficiency and fairness of Order 745 appeared in a series of articles published in The Electricity Journal.
Whether the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission reasonably
concluded that it has authority under the Federal Power Act, 16 U. S. C.
791a et seq., to regulate the rules used by operators of wholesale
electricity markets to pay for reductions in electricity consumption and
to recoup those payments through adjustments to wholesale rates.
Whether the Court of Appeals erred in holding that the rule issued
by the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission is arbitrary and capricious.[50]
On January 25, 2016, the United States Supreme Court in a 6-2 decision in FERC v. Electric Power Supply Ass'n
concluded that the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission acted within
its authority to ensure "just and reasonable" rates in the wholesale
energy market.
Demand reduction and the use of diesel generators in the UK National Grid
As of December 2009 UK National Grid had 2369 MW contracted to provide demand response, known as STOR,
the demand side provides 839 MW (35%) from 89 sites. Of this 839 MW
approximately 750 MW is back-up generation with the remaining being load
reduction.
A paper based on extensive half-hourly demand profiles and observed
electricity demand shifting for different commercial and industrial
buildings in the UK shows that only a small minority engaged in load
shifting and demand turn-down, while the majority of demand response is
provided by stand-by generators.