A set of research results indicating that listening to Mozart's music may induce a short-term improvement on the performance of certain kinds of mental tasks known as "spatial-temporal reasoning";
Popularized versions of the hypothesis, which suggest that
"listening to Mozart makes you smarter", or that early childhood
exposure to classical music has a beneficial effect on mental
development;
A US trademark
for a set of commercial recordings and related materials, which are
claimed to harness the effect for a variety of purposes. The trademark
owner, Don Campbell, Inc.,
claims benefits far beyond improving spatio-temporal reasoning or
raising intelligence, defining the mark as "an inclusive term signifying
the transformational powers of music in health, education, and
well-being."
The term was first coined by Alfred A. Tomatis who used Mozart's music
as the listening stimulus in his work attempting to cure a variety of
disorders. The approach has been popularized in Don Campbell's book, The Mozart Effect, which is based on an experiment published in Nature suggesting that listening to Mozart temporarily boosted scores on one portion of the IQ test. As a result, the United States' Governor of Georgia, Zell Miller, proposed a budget to provide every child born in Georgia with a CD of classical music.
Because of bad methodology in the first experiment and lack of replication, the Mozart effect is now believed to be a myth.
Alfred A. Tomatis
The concept of the "Mozart effect" was described by French researcher Dr. Alfred A. Tomatis in his 1991 book Pourquoi Mozart? (Why Mozart?).
He used the music of Mozart in his efforts to "retrain" the ear, and
believed that listening to the music presented at differing frequencies
helped the ear, and promoted healing and the development of the brain.
Rauscher et al. 1993 study
Frances Rauscher, Gordon Shaw, and Catherine Ky (1993) investigated the effect of listening to music by Mozart on spatial reasoning, and the results were published in Nature.
They gave research participants one of three standard tests of abstract
spatial reasoning after they had experienced each of three listening
conditions: the Sonata for Two Pianos in D major, K. 448
by Mozart, verbal relaxation instructions, and silence. They found a
temporary enhancement of spatial-reasoning, as measured by
spatial-reasoning sub tasks of the Stanford-Binet IQ test. Rauscher et
al. show that the enhancing effect of the music condition is only
temporary: no student had effects extending beyond the 15-minute period
in which they were tested. The study makes no statement of an increase
in IQ in general (because IQ was never measured).
Popularization
While
Rauscher et al. only showed an increase in "spatial intelligence", the
results were popularly interpreted as an increase in general IQ. This
misconception, and the fact that the music used in the study was by
Mozart, had an obvious appeal to those who valued this music; the Mozart
effect was thus widely reported. In 1994, New York Times music columnist Alex Ross
wrote in a light-hearted article, "researchers [Rauscher and Shaw] have
determined that listening to Mozart actually makes you smarter", and
presented this as the final piece of evidence that Mozart has dethroned Beethoven as "the world's greatest composer. " A 1997 Boston Globe
article mentioned some of the Rauscher and Shaw results. It described
one study in which three- and four-year-olds who were given eight months
of private piano lessons scored 30% higher on tests of spatio-temporal
reasoning than control groups given computer lessons, singing lessons,
and no training.
The 1997 book by Don Campbell, The Mozart Effect: Tapping the Power of Music to Heal the Body, Strengthen the Mind, and Unlock the Creative Spirit, discusses the theory that listening to Mozart (especially the piano concertos) may temporarily increase one's IQ
and produce many other beneficial effects on mental function. Campbell
recommends playing specially selected classical music to infants, in the
expectation that it will benefit their mental development.
After The Mozart Effect, Campbell wrote a follow-up book, The Mozart Effect For Children,
and created related products. Among these are collections of music that
he states harness the Mozart effect to enhance "deep rest and
rejuvenation", "intelligence and learning", and "creativity and
imagination". Campbell defines the term as "an inclusive term signifying
the transformational powers of music in health, education, and
well-being. It represents the general use of music to reduce stress,
depression, or anxiety; induce relaxation or sleep; activate the body;
and improve memory or awareness. Innovative and experimental uses of music and sound can improve listening disorders, dyslexia, attention deficit disorder, autism, and other mental and physical disorders and diseases".
These theories are controversial. The relationship of sound and
music (both played and listened to) for cognitive function and various
physiological metrics has been explored in studies with no definitive
results.
Political impact
The political impact of the theory was demonstrated on January 13, 1998, when Zell Miller, governor of Georgia,
announced that his proposed state budget would include $105,000 a year
to provide every child born in Georgia with a tape or CD of classical
music. Miller stated "No one questions that listening to music at a very
early age affects the spatial-temporal reasoning that underlies math
and engineering and even chess." Miller played legislators some of
Beethoven's "Ode to Joy" on a tape recorder and asked "Now, don't you feel smarter already?" Miller asked Yoel Levi, music director of the Atlanta Symphony, to compile a collection of classical pieces that should be included. State representative Homer DeLoach said "I asked about the possibility of including some Charlie Daniels
or something like that, but they said they thought the classical music
has a greater positive impact. Having never studied those impacts too
much, I guess I'll just have to take their word for that."
Subsequent research and meta-analyses
While some supportive reports have been published,
studies with positive results have tended to be associated with any
form of music that has energetic and positive emotional qualities.
Moreover, the intellectual benefits of enhanced mood and arousal are
not restricted to spatial-temporal reasoning, but extend to speed of
processing and creative problem solving. Among children, some studies suggest no effect on IQ or spatial ability, whereas others suggest that the effect can be elicited with energetic popular music that the children enjoy.
The weight of subsequent evidence supports either a null effect, or
short-term effects related to increases in mood and arousal, with mixed
results published after the initial report in Nature.
In 1999 a major challenge was raised to the existence of the Mozart effect by two teams of researchers. In a pair of papers published together under the title "Prelude or Requiem for the 'Mozart Effect'?" Chabris reported a meta-analysis
demonstrating that "any cognitive enhancement is small and does not
reflect any change in IQ or reasoning ability in general, but instead
derives entirely from performance on one specific type of cognitive task
and has a simple neuropsychological explanation", called "enjoyment
arousal". For example, he cites a study that found that "listening
either to Mozart or to a passage from a Stephen King
story enhanced subjects' performance in paper folding and cutting (one
of the tests frequently employed by Rauscher and Shaw) but only for
those who enjoyed what they heard". Steele et. al. found that "listening
to Mozart produced a 3-point increase relative to silence in one
experiment and a 4-point decrease in the other experiment".
In another study, the effect was replicated with the original Mozart
music, but eliminated when the tempo was slowed down and major chords
were replaced by minor chords.
Another meta-analysis by Pietschnig, Voracek, and Formann (2010)
combined results of 39 studies to answer the question as to whether or
not the Mozart Effect exists. They concluded that there is little
evidence to support the Mozart effect, as shown by small effect sizes.
However, the most striking finding in this meta-analysis is the
significantly larger effects published in studies affiliated with
Rauscher or Rideout, with effect sizes more than three times higher for
published studies affiliated with these founding members of the Mozart
Effect. These systematic moderating effects due to lab affiliation call
into question the existence of a Mozart Effect. In addition, this study
also found strong evidence supporting a confounding publication bias when effect sizes of samples who listened to Mozart are compared to samples not exposed to a stimulus.
Despite implementing Rauscher, Shaw, and Ky's (1995)
suggestions of three key components that must be present to replicate
the Mozart Effect, McCutcheon (2000) still failed to reproduce the
Mozart Effect in a study with 36 adults. These conditions were: to
ensure a task that taps into spatial components of mental imagery; a
research design that does not include a pretest to avoid ceiling
effects; a musical composition that is complex rather than repetitive
and simple. Regardless of listening to classical music, jazz or silence,
the study did not yield a significant effect on spatial reasoning
performance.
The Mozart Effect is likely just an artifact of arousal and heightened mood.
Arousal is the confounding variable that mediates the relationship
between spatial ability and music that defines the Mozart Effect.
The "neural resonance" theory of Rauscher and colleagues which contends
that Mozart's music primes the neural pathways of spatial reasoning has
been widely criticized.
Government bodies also became involved in analysing the wealth
(some 300+ articles as of 2005) of reports. A German report concluded,
for instance, that "... passively listening to Mozart — or indeed any
other music you enjoy — does not make you smarter. But more studies
should be done to find out whether music lessons could raise your
child's IQ in the long term".
Popular presentations of the "Mozart effect", including Alex
Ross's comment that "listening to Mozart actually makes you smarter" and
Zell Miller's "don't you feel smarter" query to the Georgia
legislature, almost always tie it to "intelligence." Rauscher, one of
the original researchers, has disclaimed this idea. In a 1999 reply to
an article challenging the effect, published along with the article, she wrote (emphasis added):
Our results on the effects of listening to Mozart's Sonata for Two Pianos in D Major K. 448
on spatial–temporal task performance have generated much interest but
several misconceptions, many of which are reflected in attempts to
replicate the research. The comments by Chabris and Steele et al. echo
the most common of these: that listening to Mozart enhances
intelligence. We made no such claim. The effect is limited to spatial–temporal tasks involving mental imagery and temporal ordering.
On efforts like Miller's budget proposal, and the press attention
surrounding the effect, Rauscher has said, "I don't think it can hurt.
I'm all for exposing children to wonderful cultural experiences. But I
do think the money could be better spent on music education programs."
Many scholars in the psychological community now view the claim
that playing classical music to children can boost their intelligence to
be a "myth." Emory University psychologist Scott Lilienfeld ranks Mozart Effect as number six in his book 50 Great Myths of Popular Psychology.
Health benefits
Music has been evaluated to see if it has other properties. The April 2001 edition of Journal of the Royal Society of Medicine assessed the possible health benefits of the music of Mozart.
John Jenkins played Sonata K.448 to patients with epilepsy and found a
decrease in epileptiform activity. According to the British Epilepsy
Organization, research has suggested that apart from Mozart's K.448 and Piano Concerto No. 23 (K. 488), only one other piece of music has been found to have a similar effect; a song by the Greek composer Yanni, entitled "Acroyali/Standing in Motion" (version from Yanni Live at the Acropolis performed at the Acropolis). It was determined to have the "Mozart effect", by the Journal of the Royal Society of Medicine because it was similar to Mozart's K.448 in tempo, structure, melodic and harmonic consonance and predictability.
Other uses of Mozart's music
While
it is clear that exposure to Mozart does not raise IQ, studies of the
effects of music have explored as diverse areas as its links to seizure onset or research in animals suggesting that even exposure in-utero in rats improves their maze learning. The original claim continues to influence public life. For instance a German sewage treatment plant plays Mozart music to break down the waste faster, reports the UK Guardian. Anton Stucki, chief operator of the Treuenbrietzen
plant was quoted as saying, "We think the secret is in the vibrations
of the music, which penetrate everything—including the water, the sewage
and the cells."
The law of comparative advantage describes how, under free trade, an agent will produce more of and consume less of a good for which they have a comparative advantage.
In an economic model, agents have a comparative advantage over others in producing a particular good if they can produce that good at a lower relative opportunity cost or autarky price, i.e. at a lower relative marginal cost prior to trade. Comparative advantage describes the economic reality of the work gains from trade for individuals, firms, or nations, which arise from differences in their factor endowments or technological progress.
(One should not compare the monetary costs of production or even the
resource costs (labor needed per unit of output) of production. Instead,
one must compare the opportunity costs of producing goods across countries).
David Ricardo developed the classical theory of comparative advantage in 1817 to explain why countries engage in international trade even when one country's workers are more efficient at producing every
single good than workers in other countries. He demonstrated that if
two countries capable of producing two commodities engage in the free market,
then each country will increase its overall consumption by exporting
the good for which it has a comparative advantage while importing the
other good, provided that there exist differences in labor productivity between both countries. Widely regarded as one of the most powerful yet counter-intuitive insights in economics, Ricardo's theory implies that comparative advantage rather than absolute advantage is responsible for much of international trade.
Classical theory and David Ricardo's formulation
Adam Smith first alluded to the concept of absolute advantage as the basis for international trade in 1776, in The Wealth of Nations:
If a foreign country can supply us
with a commodity cheaper than we ourselves can make it, better buy it
off them with some part of the produce of our own industry employed in a
way in which we have some advantage. The general industry of the
country, being always in proportion to the capital which employs it,
will not thereby be diminished [...] but only left to find out the way
in which it can be employed with the greatest advantage.
Writing several decades after Smith in 1808, Robert Torrens articulated a preliminary definition of comparative advantage as the loss from the closing of trade:
[I]f I wish to know the extent of the advantage, which arises to England, from her giving France a hundred pounds of broadcloth,
in exchange for a hundred pounds of lace, I take the quantity of lace
which she has acquired by this transaction, and compare it with the
quantity which she might, at the same expense of labour and capital,
have acquired by manufacturing it at home. The lace that remains, beyond
what the labour and capital employed on the cloth, might have
fabricated at home, is the amount of the advantage which England derives
from the exchange.
Graph illustrating Ricardo's example:
In case I (diamonds), each country spends 3600 hours to produce a mixture of cloth and wine.
In case II (squares), each country specializes in its comparative advantage, resulting in greater total output.
In a famous example, Ricardo considers a world economy consisting of two countries, Portugal and England, each producing two goods of identical quality. In Portugal, the a priori more efficient country, it is possible to produce wine and cloth
with less labor than it would take to produce the same quantities in
England. However, the relative costs of producing those two goods differ
between the countries.
Hours of work necessary to produce one unit
Produce
Country
Cloth
Wine
England
100
120
Portugal
90
80
In this illustration, England could commit 100 hours of labor to produce one unit of cloth, or produce 5/6 units of wine. Meanwhile, in comparison, Portugal could commit 90 hours of labor to produce one unit of cloth, or produce 9/8 units of wine. So, Portugal possesses an absolute advantage in producing cloth due to fewer labor hours, but England has a comparative advantage in producing cloth due to lower opportunity cost.
In the absence of trade, England requires 220 hours of work to
both produce and consume one unit each of cloth and wine while Portugal
requires 170 hours of work to produce and consume the same quantities.
England is more efficient at producing cloth than wine, and Portugal is
more efficient at producing wine than cloth. So, if each country
specializes in the good for which it has a comparative advantage, then
the global production of both goods increases, for England can spend 220
labor hours to produce 2.2 units of cloth while Portugal can spend 170
hours to produce 2.125 units of wine. Moreover, if both countries
specialize in the above manner and England trades a unit of its cloth
for 5/6 to 9/8
units of Portugal's wine, then both countries can consume at least a
unit each of cloth and wine, with 0 to 0.2 units of cloth and 0 to 0.125
units of wine remaining in each respective country to be consumed or
exported. Consequently, both England and Portugal can consume more wine
and cloth under free trade than in autarky.
Ricardian model
The Ricardian model is a general equilibrium mathematical model of international trade. Although the idea of the Ricardian model was first presented in the Essay on Profits (a single-commodity version) and then in the Principles (a multi-commodity version) by David Ricardo, the first mathematical Ricardian model was published by William Whewell in 1833. The earliest test of the Ricardian model was performed by G.D.A MacDougall, which was published in Economic Journal of 1951 and 1952. In the Ricardian model, trade patterns depend on productivity differences.
The following is a typical modern interpretation of the classical Ricardian model. In the interest of simplicity, it uses notation and definitions, such as opportunity cost, unavailable to Ricardo.
The world economy consists of two countries, Home and Foreign,
which produce wine and cloth. Labor, the only factor of production, is mobile
domestically but not internationally; there may be migration between
sectors but not between countries. We denote the labor force in Home by , the amount of labor required to produce one unit of wine in Home by , and the amount of labor required to produce one unit of cloth in Home by . The total amount of wine and cloth produced in Home are and respectively. We denote the same variables for Foreign by appending a prime. For instance, is the amount of labor needed to produce a unit of wine in Foreign.
We don't know if Home is more productive than Foreign in making cloth. That is, we don't know that . Similarly, we don't know if Home has an absolute advantage in wine. However, we will assume that Home is more relatively productive in cloth than Foreign:
Equivalently, we may assume that Home has a comparative advantage in
cloth in the sense that it has a lower opportunity cost for cloth in
terms of wine than Foreign:
In the absence of trade, the relative price of cloth and wine in each
country is determined solely by the relative labor cost of the goods.
Hence the relative autarky price of cloth is in Home and in Foreign. With free trade, the price of cloth or wine in either country is the world price or.
Instead of considering the world demand (or supply) for cloth and wine, we are interested in the world relative demand (or relative supply)
for cloth and wine, which we define as the ratio of the world demand
(or supply) for cloth to the world demand (or supply) for wine. In
general equilibrium, the world relative price will be determined uniquely by the intersection of world relative demand and world relative supply curves.
The demand for cloth relative to wine decreases with the relative price of cloth in terms of wine; the supply of cloth relative to wine increases with relative price. Two relative demand curves and are drawn for illustrative purposes.
We assume that the relative demand curve reflects substitution
effects and is decreasing with respect to relative price. The behavior
of the relative supply curve, however, warrants closer study. Recalling
our original assumption that Home has a comparative advantage in cloth,
we consider five possibilities for the relative quantity supplied at a
given price.
If , then Foreign specializes in wine, for the wage in the wine sector is greater than the wage
in the cloth sector. However, Home workers are indifferent between
working in either sector. As a result, the quantity supplied can take
any value.
If , then both Home and Foreign specialize in wine, for similar reasons as above, and so the quantity supplied is zero.
If , then Home specializes in cloth whereas Foreign specializes in wine. The quantity supplied is given by the ratio of the world production of cloth to the world production of wine.
If ,
then both Home and Foreign specialize in cloth. The quantity supplied
tends to infinity as the quantity of wine supplied approaches zero.
If ,
then Home specializes in cloth while Foreign workers are indifferent
between sectors. Again, the relative quantity supplied can take any
value.
The
blue triangle depicts Home's original production (and consumption)
possibilities. By trading, Home can also consume bundles in the pink
triangle despite facing the same productions possibility frontier.
As long as the relative demand is finite, the relative price is always bounded by the inequality
from which it follows that Home's cloth consumption at the production possibilities frontier is
.
With free trade, Home produces cloth exclusively, an amount of which
it exports in exchange for wine at the prevailing rate. Thus Home's
overall consumption is now subject to the constraint
while its cloth consumption at the consumption possibilities frontier is given by
.
A symmetric argument holds for Foreign. Therefore, by trading and
specializing in a good for which it has a comparative advantage, each
country can expand its consumption possibilities. Consumers can choose
from bundles of wine and cloth that they could not have produced
themselves in closed economies.
Terms of trade
Terms
of trade is the rate at which one good could be traded for another. If
both countries specialize in the good for which they have a comparative
advantage then trade, the terms of trade for a good (that benefit both
entities) will fall between each entities opportunity costs. In the
example above one unit of cloth would trade for between units of wine and units of wine.
Haberler's opportunity costs formulation
In
1930 Gottfried Haberler detached the doctrine of comparative advantage
from Ricardo's labor theory of value and provided a modern
opportunity-cost formulation. Haberler's reformulation of comparative
advantage revolutionized the theory of international trade and laid the
conceptual groundwork of modern trade theories.
Haberler's innovation was to reformulate the theory of
comparative advantage such that the value of good X is measured in terms
of the forgone units of production of good Y rather than the labor
units necessary to produce good X, as in the Ricardian formulation.
Haberler implemented this opportunity-cost formulation of comparative
advantage by introducing the concept of a production possibility curve
into international trade theory.
Modern theories
Since 1817, economists have attempted to generalize the Ricardian model and derive the principle of comparative advantage in broader settings, most notably in the neoclassicalspecific factorsRicardo-Viner (which allows for the model to include more factors than just labour) and factor proportionsHeckscher–Ohlin models. Subsequent developments in the new trade theory, motivated in part by the empirical shortcomings of the H–O model and its inability to explain intra-industry trade, have provided an explanation for aspects of trade that are not accounted for by comparative advantage. Nonetheless, economists like Alan Deardorff, Avinash Dixit, Gottfried Haberler, and Victor D. Norman have responded with weaker generalizations of the principle of comparative advantage, in which countries will only tend to export goods for which they have a comparative advantage.
Dornbusch et al.'s continuum of goods formulation
In
both the Ricardian and H–O models, the comparative advantage theory is
formulated for a 2 countries/2 commodities case. It can be extended to a
2 countries/many commodities case, or a many countries/2 commodities
case. Adding commodities in order to have a smooth continuum of goods is
the major insight of the seminal paper by Dornbusch, Fisher, and
Samuelson. In fact, inserting an increasing number of goods into the
chain of comparative advantage makes the gaps between the ratios of the
labor requirements negligible, in which case the three types of
equilibria around any good in the original model collapse to the same
outcome. It notably allows for transportation costs to be incorporated,
although the framework remains restricted to two countries.
But in the case with many countries (more than 3 countries) and many
commodities (more than 3 commodities), the notion of comparative
advantage requires a substantially more complex formulation.
Deardorff's general law of comparative advantage
Skeptics
of comparative advantage have underlined that its theoretical
implications hardly hold when applied to individual commodities or pairs
of commodities in a world of multiple commodities. Deardorff argues
that the insights of comparative advantage remain valid if the theory is
restated in terms of averages across all commodities. His models
provide multiple insights on the correlations between vectors of trade
and vectors with relative-autarky-price measures of comparative
advantage. What has become to be known as the "Deardorff's general law
of comparative advantage" is a model incorporating multiple goods, and
which takes into account tariffs, transportation costs, and other
obstacles to trade.
Alternative approaches
Recently, Y. Shiozawa succeeded in constructing a theory of international value in the tradition of Ricardo's cost-of-production theory of value.
This was based on a wide range of assumptions: Many countries; Many
commodities; Several production techniques for a product in a country;
Input trade (intermediate goods
are freely traded); Durable capital goods with constant efficiency
during a predetermined lifetime; No transportation cost (extendable to
positive cost cases).
In a famous comment McKenzie pointed that "A moment's
consideration will convince one that Lancashire would be unlikely to
produce cotton cloth if the cotton had to be grown in England."
However, McKenzie and later researchers could not produce a general
theory which includes traded input goods because of the mathematical
difficulty.
As John Chipman points it, McKenzie found that "introduction of trade
in intermediate product necessitates a fundamental alteration in
classical analysis."
Durable capital goods such as machines and installations are inputs to
the productions in the same title as part and ingredients.
In view of the new theory, no physical criterion exists.
The competitive patterns are determined by the traders trials to find
cheapest products in a world. The search of cheapest product is achieved
by world optimal procurement. Thus the new theory explains how the
global supply chains are formed.
Empirical approach to comparative advantage
Comparative
advantage is a theory about the benefits that specialization and trade
would bring, rather than a strict prediction about actual behavior. (In
practice, governments restrict international trade for a variety of
reasons; under Ulysses S. Grant,
the US postponed opening up to free trade until its industries were up
to strength, following the example set earlier by Britain.) Nonetheless there is a large amount of empirical
work testing the predictions of comparative advantage. The empirical
works usually involve testing predictions of a particular model. For
example, the Ricardian model predicts that technological differences in
countries result in differences in labor productivity. The differences
in labor productivity in turn determine the comparative advantages
across different countries. Testing the Ricardian model for instance
involves looking at the relationship between relative labor productivity
and international trade patterns. A country that is relatively
efficient in producing shoes tends to export shoes.
Direct test: natural experiment of Japan
Assessing
the validity of comparative advantage on a global scale with the
examples of contemporary economies is analytically challenging because
of the multiple factors driving globalization: indeed, investment,
migration, and technological change play a role in addition to trade.
Even if we could isolate the workings of open trade from other
processes, establishing its causal impact also remains complicated: it
would require a comparison with a counterfactual world without open
trade. Considering the durability of different aspects of globalization,
it is hard to assess the sole impact of open trade on a particular
economy.
Daniel Bernhofen
and John Brown have attempted to address this issue, by using a natural
experiment of a sudden transition to open trade in a market economy.
They focus on the case of Japan.
The Japanese economy indeed developed over several centuries under
autarky and a quasi-isolation from international trade but was, by the
mid-19th century, a sophisticated market economy with a population of 30
million. Under Western military pressure, Japan opened its economy to
foreign trade through a series of unequal treaties.
In 1859, the treaties limited tariffs to 5% and opened trade to
Westerners. Considering that the transition from autarky, or
self-sufficiency, to open trade was brutal, few changes to the
fundamentals of the economy occurred in the first 20 years of trade. The
general law of comparative advantage theorizes that an economy should,
on average, export goods with low self-sufficiency prices and import
goods with high self-sufficiency prices. Bernhofen and Brown found that
by 1869, the price of Japan's main export, silk and derivatives, saw a
100% increase in real terms, while the prices of numerous imported goods
declined of 30-75%. In the next decade, the ratio of imports to gross
domestic product reached 4%.
Structural estimation
Another
important way of demonstrating the validity of comparative advantage
has consisted in 'structural estimation' approaches. These approaches
have built on the Ricardian formulation of two goods for two countries
and subsequent models with many goods or many countries. The aim has
been to reach a formulation accounting for both multiple goods and
multiple countries, in order to reflect real-world conditions more
accurately. Jonathan Eaton and Samuel Kortum underlined that a
convincing model needed to incorporate the idea of a 'continuum of
goods' developed by Dornbusch et al. for both goods and countries. They
were able to do so by allowing for an arbitrary (integer) number i of
countries, and dealing exclusively with unit labor requirements for each
good (one for each point on the unit interval) in each country (of
which there are i).
Earlier empirical work
Two of the first tests of comparative advantage were by MacDougall (1951, 1952).
A prediction of a two-country Ricardian comparative advantage model is
that countries will export goods where output per worker (i.e.
productivity) is higher. That is, we expect a positive relationship
between output per worker and number of exports. MacDougall tested this
relationship with data from the US and UK, and did indeed find a
positive relationship. The statistical test of this positive
relationship was replicated with new data by Stern (1962) and Balassa (1963).
Dosi et al. (1988)
conduct a book-length empirical examination that suggests that
international trade in manufactured goods is largely driven by
differences in national technological competencies.
One critique of the textbook model of comparative advantage is
that there are only two goods. The results of the model are robust to
this assumption. Dornbusch et al. (1977)
generalized the theory to allow for such a large number of goods as to
form a smooth continuum. Based in part on these generalizations of the
model, Davis (1995) provides a more recent view of the Ricardian approach to explain trade between countries with similar resources.
More recently, Golub and Hsieh (2000)
presents modern statistical analysis of the relationship between
relative productivity and trade patterns, which finds reasonably strong
correlations, and Nunn (2007)
finds that countries that have greater enforcement of contracts
specialize in goods that require relationship-specific investments.
Taking a broader perspective, there has been work about the benefits of international trade. Zimring & Etkes (2014) finds that the Blockade of the Gaza Strip,
which substantially restricted the availability of imports to Gaza, saw
labor productivity fall by 20% in three years. Markusen et al. (1994) reports the effects of moving away from autarky to free trade during the Meiji Restoration, with the result that national income increased by up to 65% in 15 years.
Considerations
Development economics
The theory of comparative advantage, and the corollary that nations
should specialize, is criticized on pragmatic grounds within the import substitution industrialization theory of development economics, on empirical grounds by the Singer–Prebisch thesis
which states that terms of trade between primary producers and
manufactured goods deteriorate over time, and on theoretical grounds of infant industry and Keynesian economics. In older economic terms, comparative advantage has been opposed by mercantilism and economic nationalism.
These argue instead that while a country may initially be comparatively
disadvantaged in a given industry (such as Japanese cars in the 1950s),
countries should shelter and invest in industries until they become
globally competitive. Further, they argue that comparative advantage, as
stated, is a static theory – it does not account for the possibility of
advantage changing through investment or economic development, and thus
does not provide guidance for long-term economic development.
Much has been written since Ricardo as commerce has evolved and
cross-border trade has become more complicated. Today trade policy tends
to focus more on "competitive advantage"
as opposed to "comparative advantage". One of the most in-depth
research undertakings on "competitive advantage" was conducted in the
1980s as part of the Reagan administration's Project Socrates
to establish the foundation for a technology-based competitive strategy
development system that could be used for guiding international trade
policy.
Criticism
Several
arguments have been advanced against using comparative advantage as a
justification for advocating free trade, and they have gained an
audience among economists. For example, James Brander and Barbara Spencer
demonstrated how, in a strategic setting where a few firms compete for
the world market, export subsidies and import restrictions can keep
foreign firms from competing with national firms, increasing welfare in
the country implementing these so-called strategic trade policies.
However, the overwhelming consensus of the economics profession
remains that while these arguments against comparative advantage are
theoretically valid under certain conditions or assumptions, these
assumptions do not usually hold. Thus, these arguments should not be
used to guide trade policy. Gregory Mankiw,
chairman of the Harvard Economics Department, has stated: ″Few
propositions command as much consensus among professional economists as
that open world trade increases economic growth and raises living
standards.″
There are some economists who dispute the claims of the benefit of comparative advantage. James K. Galbraith has stated that "free trade has attained the status of a god" and that "...
none of the world's most successful trading regions, including Japan,
Korea, Taiwan, and now mainland China, reached their current status by
adopting neoliberal trading rules." He argues that "... comparative advantage is based upon the concept of constant returns:
the idea that you can double or triple the output of any good simply by
doubling or tripling the inputs. But this is not generally the case.
For manufactured products, increasing returns, learning, and technical
change are the rule, not the exception; the cost of production falls
with experience. With increasing returns, the lowest cost will be
incurred by the country that starts earliest and moves fastest on any
particular line. Potential competitors have to protect their own
industries if they wish them to survive long enough to achieve
competitive scale."
According to Galbraith, nations trapped into specializing in
agriculture are condemned to perpetual poverty, as agriculture is
dependent on land, a finite non-increasing natural resource. Galbraith
summarizes: "Comparative advantage has very little practical use for
trade strategy. Diversification, not specialization, is the main path
out of underdevelopment, and effective diversification requires a
strategic approach to trade policy. It cannot mean walling off the
outside world, but it is also a goal not easily pursued under a dogmatic
commitment to free trade."
According to historian Cecil Woodham-Smith,
Ireland in the 1800s is an example of the dangers of
over-specialization. When the union with Great Britain was formed in
1800, Irish textile industries protected by tariffs were exposed to
world markets where England had a comparative advantage in technology,
experience and scale of operation which devastated the Irish industry.
Ireland was forced to specialize in the export of grain while the
displaced Irish labor was forced into subsistence farming and relying on
the potato for survival. When the potato blight occurred the resulting
famine killed at least one million Irish in one of the worst famines in
European history. As Woodham-Smith would later comment, "the Irish
peasant was told to replace the potato by eating his grain, but Trevelyan
once again refused to take any steps to curb the export of food from
Ireland. 'Do not encourage the idea of prohibiting exports,' he wrote,
on September 3, (1846) 'perfect free trade is the right course'."
Free trade is based on the theory of comparative advantage.
The classical and neoclassical formulations of comparative advantage
theory differ in the tools they use but share the same basis and logic.
Comparative advantage theory says that market forces lead all factors of
production to their best use in the economy. It indicates that
international free trade would be beneficial for all participating
countries as well as for the world as a whole because they could
increase their overall production and consume more by specializing
according to their comparative advantages. Goods would become cheaper
and available in larger quantities. Moreover, this specialization would
not be the result of chance or political intent, but would be
automatic. However according to non-neoclassical economists, the theory
is based on assumptions that are neither theoretically nor empirically
valid.
International mobility of capital and labour
The international immobility of labour and capital is essential to
the theory of comparative advantage. Without this, there would be no
reason for international free trade to be regulated by comparative
advantages. Classical and neoclassical economists all assume that labour
and capital do not circulate between nations. At the international
level, only the goods produced can move freely, with capital and labour
trapped in countries. David Ricardo was aware that the international
immobility of labour and capital is an indispensable hypothesis. He
devoted half of his explanation of the theory to it in his book. He even
explained that if labour and capital could move internationally, then
comparative advantages could not determine international trade. Ricardo
assumed that the reasons for the immobility of the capital would be:
"the fancied or real insecurity of
capital, when not under the immediate control of its owner, together
with the natural disinclination which every man has to quit the country
of his birth and connexions, and intrust himself with all his habits
fixed, to a strange government and new laws"
Neoclassical economists, for their part, argue that the scale of
these movements of workers and capital is negligible. They developed the
theory of price compensation by factor that makes these movements
superfluous.
In practice, however, workers move in large numbers from one country to
another. Today, labour migration is truly a global phenomenon. And, with
the reduction in transport and communication costs, capital has become
increasingly mobile and frequently moves from one country to another.
Moreover, the neoclassical assumption that factors are trapped at the
national level has no theoretical basis and the assumption of factor
price equalisation cannot justify international immobility. Moreover,
there is no evidence that factor prices are equal worldwide. Comparative
advantages cannot therefore determine the structure of international
trade.
If they are internationally mobile and the most productive use of
factors is in another country, then free trade will lead them to
migrate to that country. This will benefit the nation to which they
emigrate, but not necessarily the others.
Externalities
An externality is the term used when the price of a product does not
reflect its cost or real economic value. The classic negative
externality is environmental degradation, which reduces the value of
natural resources without increasing the price of the product that has
caused them harm. The classic positive externality is technological
encroachment, where one company's invention of a product allows others
to copy or build on it, generating wealth that the original company
cannot capture. If prices are wrong due to positive or negative
externalities, free trade will produce sub-optimal results.
For example, goods from a country with lax pollution standards
will be too cheap. As a result, its trading partners will import too
much. And the exporting country will export too much, concentrating its
economy too much in industries that are not as profitable as they seem,
ignoring the damage caused by pollution.
On the positive externalities, if an industry generates
technological spinoffs for the rest of the economy, then free trade can
let that industry be destroyed by foreign competition because the
economy ignores its hidden value. Some industries generate new
technologies, allow improvements in other industries and stimulate
technological advances throughout the economy; losing these industries
means losing all industries that would have resulted in the future.
Cross-industrial movement of productive resources
Comparative advantage theory deals with the best use of resources and
how to put the economy to its best use. But this implies that the
resources used to manufacture one product can be used to produce another
object. If they cannot, imports will not push the economy into
industries better suited to its comparative advantage and will only
destroy existing industries.
For example, when workers cannot move from one industry to
another—usually because they do not have the right skills or do not live
in the right place—changes in the economy's comparative advantage will
not shift them to a more appropriate industry, but rather to
unemployment or precarious and unproductive jobs.
Static vs. dynamic gains via international trade
Comparative advantage theory allows for a "static" and not a
"dynamic" analysis of the economy. That is, it examines the facts at a
single point in time and determines the best response to those facts at
that point in time, given our productivity in various industries. But
when it comes to long-term growth, it says nothing about how the facts
can change tomorrow and how they can be changed in someone's favour. It
does not indicate how best to transform factors of production into more
productive factors in the future.
According to theory, the only advantage of international trade is
that goods become cheaper and available in larger quantities. Improving
the static efficiency of existing resources would therefore be the only
advantage of international trade. And the neoclassical formulation
assumes that the factors of production are given only exogenously.
Exogenous changes can come from population growth, industrial policies,
the rate of capital accumulation (propensity for security) and
technological inventions, among others. Dynamic developments endogenous
to trade such as economic growth are not integrated into Ricardo's
theory. And this is not affected by what is called "dynamic comparative
advantage". In these models, comparative advantages develop and change
over time, but this change is not the result of trade itself, but of a
change in exogenous factors.
However, the world, and in particular the industrialized
countries, are characterized by dynamic gains endogenous to trade, such
as technological growth that has led to an increase in the standard of
living and wealth of the industrialized world. In addition, dynamic
gains are more important than static gains.
Balanced trade and adjustment mechanisms
A crucial assumption in both the classical and neoclassical
formulation of comparative advantage theory is that trade is balanced,
which means that the value of imports is equal to the value of each
country's exports. The volume of trade may change, but international
trade will always be balanced at least after a certain adjustment
period. The balance of trade is essential for theory because the
resulting adjustment mechanism is responsible for transforming the
comparative advantages of production costs into absolute price
advantages. And this is necessary because it is the absolute price
differences that determine the international flow of goods. Since
consumers buy a good from the one who sells it cheapest, comparative
advantages in terms of production costs must be transformed into
absolute price advantages. In the case of floating exchange rates, it is
the exchange rate adjustment mechanism that is responsible for this
transformation of comparative advantages into absolute price advantages.
In the case of fixed exchange rates, neoclassical theory suggests that
trade is balanced by changes in wage rates.
So if trade were not balanced in itself and if there were no
adjustment mechanism, there would be no reason to achieve a comparative
advantage. However, trade imbalances are the norm and balanced trade is
in practice only an exception. In addition, financial crises such as the
Asian crisis of the 1990s show that balance of payments imbalances are
rarely benign and do not self-regulate. There is no adjustment mechanism
in practice. Comparative advantages do not turn into price differences
and therefore cannot explain international trade flows.
Thus, theory can very easily recommend a trade policy that gives
us the highest possible standard of living in the short term but none in
the long term. This is what happens when a nation runs a trade deficit,
which necessarily means that it goes into debt with foreigners or sells
its existing assets to them. Thus, the nation applies a frenzy of
consumption in the short term followed by a long-term decline.
International trade as bartering
The assumption that trade will always be balanced is a corollary of
the fact that trade is understood as barter. The definition of
international trade as barter trade is the basis for the assumption of
balanced trade. Ricardo insists that international trade takes place as
if it were purely a barter trade, a presumption that is maintained by
subsequent classical and neoclassical economists. The quantity of money
theory, which Ricardo uses, assumes that money is neutral and neglects
the velocity of a currency. Money has only one function in
international trade, namely as a means of exchange to facilitate trade.
In practice, however, the velocity of circulation is not
constant and the quantity of money is not neutral for the real economy. A
capitalist world is not characterized by a barter economy but by a
market economy. The main difference in the context of international
trade is that sales and purchases no longer necessarily have to
coincide. The seller is not necessarily obliged to buy immediately.
Thus, money is not only a means of exchange. It is above all a means of
payment and is also used to store value, settle debts and transfer
wealth. Thus, unlike the barter hypothesis of the comparative advantage
theory, money is not a commodity like any other. Rather, it is of
practical importance to specifically own money rather than any
commodity. And money as a store of value in a world of uncertainty has a
significant influence on the motives and decisions of wealth holders
and producers.
Using labour and capital to their full potential
Ricardo and later classical economists assume that labour tends
towards full employment and that capital is always fully used in a
liberalized economy, because no capital owner will leave its capital
unused but will always seek to make a profit from it. That there is no
limit to the use of capital is a consequence of Jean-Baptiste Say's law,
which presumes that production is limited only by resources and is also
adopted by neoclassical economists.
From a theoretical point of view, comparative advantage theory
must assume that labour or capital is used to its full potential and
that resources limit production. There are two reasons for this: the
realization of gains through international trade and the adjustment
mechanism. In addition, this assumption is necessary for the concept of
opportunity costs. If unemployment (or underutilized resources) exists,
there are no opportunity costs, because the production of one good can
be increased without reducing the production of another good. Since
comparative advantages are determined by opportunity costs in the
neoclassical formulation, these cannot be calculated and this
formulation would lose its logical basis.
If a country's resources were not fully utilized, production and
consumption could be increased at the national level without
participating in international trade. The whole raison d'être of
international trade would disappear, as would the possible gains. In
this case, a State could even earn more by refraining from participating
in international trade and stimulating domestic production, as this
would allow it to employ more labour and capital and increase national
income. Moreover, any adjustment mechanism underlying the theory no
longer works if unemployment exists.
In practice, however, the world is characterised by unemployment.
Unemployment and underemployment of capital and labour are not a
short-term phenomenon, but it is common and widespread. Unemployment and
untapped resources are more the rule than the exception.