Subject classifications
The
subject may be categorized in various ways, depending on specificity,
intersection, and cross-classification. For example, within the Journal of Economic Literature classification codes, it has been categorized under:
- Welfare economics at JEL: D63 – Equity, Justice, Inequality, and Other Normative Criteria and Measurement
- Health, education, and welfare at JEL: I31 – General Welfare; Basic needs; Living standards; Quality of life; Happiness
- Demographic economics at JEL:J18 – Public Policy.
Metrology
Given its very nature, reported happiness is subjective. It is difficult to compare one person's happiness with another's. It can be especially difficult to compare happiness across cultures.
However, many happiness economists believe they have solved this
comparison problem. Cross-sections of large data samples across nations
and time demonstrate consistent patterns in the determinants of
happiness.
Happiness is typically measured using subjective measures – e.g.
self-reported surveys – and/or objective measures. One concern has
always been the accuracy and reliability of people's responses to happiness surveys.
Objective measures such as lifespan, income, and education are often
used as well as or instead of subjectively reported happiness, though
this assumes that they generally produce happiness, which while
plausible may not necessarily be the case. The terms quality of life or well-being are often used to encompass these more objective measures.
Some scientists claim that happiness can be measured both subjectively and objectively by observing the joy center of the brain lit up with advanced imaging, although this raises philosophical issues, for example about whether this can be treated as more reliable than reported subjective happiness.
Micro-econometric happiness equations have the standard form: . In this equation is the reported well-being of individual at time , and is a vector of known variables, which include socio-demographic and socioeconomic characteristics.
Happiness, well-being, or satisfaction with life, was seen as unmeasurable in classical and neo-classical economics. Van Praag
was the first person who organized large surveys in order to explicitly
measure welfare derived from income. He did this with the Income
Evaluation Question (IEQ). This approach is called the Leyden School.
It is named after the Dutch university where this approach was
developed. Other Researchers included Arie Kapteyn and Aldi Hagenaars.
Determinants
GDP and GNP
Typically national financial measures, such as gross domestic product (GDP) and gross national product
(GNP), have been used as a measure of successful policy. There is a
significant association between GDP and happiness, with citizens in
wealthier nations being happier than those in poorer nations. It has been argued that this relationship extends only to an average GDP per capita of about $15,000. In the 2000s, several studies have obtained the opposite result, so this Easterlin paradox is controversial.
Individual income
Historically,
economists have said that well-being is a simple function of income.
However, it has been found that once wealth reaches a subsistence level,
its effectiveness as a generator of well-being is greatly diminished.
Happiness economists hope to change the way governments view well-being
and how to most effectively govern and allocate resources given this
paradox.
In 2010, Daniel Kahneman and Angus Deaton
found that higher earners generally reported better life satisfaction,
but people's day-to-day emotional well-being only rose with earnings
until a threshold annual income of $75,000.
Other factors have been suggested as making people happier than money.
A short term course of psychological therapy is 32 times more cost
effective at increasing happiness than simply increasing income.
Scholars at the University of Virginia, University of British
Columbia and Harvard University released a study in 2011 after examining
numerous academic paper in response to an apparent contradiction: "When
asked to take stock of their lives, people with more money report being
a good deal more satisfied. But when asked how happy they are at the
moment, people with more money are barely different than those with
less." Published in the Journal of Consumer Psychology, the study
is entitled "If Money Doesn't Make You Happy, Then You Probably Aren't
Spending It Right" and included the following eight general
recommendations:
- Spend money on "experiences" rather than goods.
- Donate money to others, including charities, rather than spending it solely on oneself.
- Spend small amounts of money on many small, temporary pleasures rather than less often on larger ones.
- Don't spend money on "extended warranties and other forms of overpriced insurance."
- Adjust one's mindset to "pay now, consume later," instead of "consume now, pay later."
- Exercise circumspection about the day-to-day consequences of a purchase beforehand.
- Rather than buying products that provide the "best deal," make purchases based on what will facilitate well-being.
- Seek out the opinions of other people who have prior experience of a product before purchasing it.
In their "Unhappy Cities" paper, Edward Glaeser, Joshua Gottlieb and
Oren Ziv examined the self-reported subjective well-being of people
living in American metropolitan areas, particularly in relation to the
notion that "individuals make trade-offs among competing objectives,
including but not limited to happiness." The researchers findings
revealed that people living in metropolitan areas where lower levels of
happiness are reported are receiving higher real wages, and they suggest
in their conclusion that "humans are quite understandably willing to
sacrifice both happiness and life satisfaction if the price is right."
Social security
Ruut Veenhoven
claimed that social security payments do not seem to add to happiness.
This may be due to the fact that non-self-earned income (e.g., from a
lottery) does not add to happiness in general either.
Happiness may be the mind's reward to a useful action. However, Johan
Norberg of CIS, a free enterprise economy think tank, presents a
hypothesis that as people who think that they themselves control their
lives are more happy, paternalist institutions may decrease happiness.
An alternative perspective focuses on the role of the welfare
state as an institution that improves quality of life not only by
increasing the extent to which basic human needs are met, but also by
promoting greater control of one's life by limiting the degree to which
individuals find themselves at the mercy of impersonal market forces
that are indifferent to the fate of individuals. This is the argument
suggested by the U.S. political scientist Benjamin Radcliff,
who has presented a series of papers in peer reviewed scholarly
journals demonstrating that a more generous welfare state contributes to
higher levels of life satisfaction, and does so to rich and poor alike.
Employment
Generally, the well-being of those who are employed is higher than those who are unemployed.
Employment itself may not increase subjective well-being, but
facilitates activities that do (such as supporting a family,
philanthropy, and education). While work does increase well-being
through providing income, income level is not as indicative of
subjective well-being as other benefits related to employment.
Feelings of autonomy and mastery, found in higher levels in the
employed than unemployed, are stronger predictors of subjective
well-being than wealth.
When personal preference and the amount of time spent working do
not align, both men and women experience a decrease in subjective
well-being.
The negative effect of working more or working less than preferred has
been found across multiple studies, most finding that working more than
preferred (over-employed) is more detrimental, but some found that
working less (under-employed) is more detrimental.
Most individuals' levels of subjective well-being returned to "normal"
(level previous to time mismatch) within one year. Levels remained lower
only when individuals worked more hours than preferred for a period of
two years or more, which may indicate that it is more detrimental to be
over-employed than under-employed in the long-term.
Employment status effects are not confined to the individual.
Being unemployed can have detrimental effects on a spouse's subjective
well-being, compared to being employed or not working (and not looking
for work).
Partner life satisfaction is inversely related to the number of hours
their partner is underemployed. When both partners are underemployed,
the life-satisfaction of men is more greatly diminished than women. However, just being in a relationship reduces the impact unemployment has on the subjective well-being of an individual. On a broad scale, high rates of unemployment negatively affect the subjective well-being of the employed.
Becoming self-employed can increase subjective well-being, given
the right conditions. Those who leave work to become self-employed
report greater life satisfaction than those who work for others or
become self-employed after unemployment; this effect increases over
time.
Those who are self-employed and have employees of their own report
higher life-satisfaction than those who are self-employed without
employees, and women who are self-employed without employees report a
higher life satisfaction than men in the same condition.
The effects of retirement on subjective well-being vary depending
on personal and cultural factors. Subjective well-being can remain
stable for those who retire from work voluntarily, but declines for
those who are involuntarily retired.
In countries with an average social norm to work, the well-being of men
increases after retirement, and the well-being of retired women is at
the same level as women who are homemakers or work outside the home. In countries with a strong social norm to work, retirement negatively impacts the well-being of men and women.
Relationships and children
Relative
declines in female happiness have eroded a gender gap in happiness in
which women in the 1970s typically reported higher subjective well-being
than did men.
In rich societies, where a rise in income doesn't equate to an
increase in levels of subjective well-being, personal relationships are
the determining factors of happiness.
Glaeser, Gottlieb and Ziv suggest in their conclusion that the
happiness trade-offs that individuals seem willing to make aligns with
the tendency of parents to report less happiness, as they sacrifice
their personal well-being for the "price" of having children.
Freedom and control
There is a significant correlation between feeling in control of one's own life and happiness levels.
A study conducted at the University of Zurich suggested that democracy and federalism bring well-being to individuals.
It concluded that the more direct political participation
possibilities available to citizens raises their subjective well-being.
Two reasons were given for this finding. First, a more active role
for citizens enables better monitoring of professional politicians by
citizens, which leads to greater satisfaction with government output.
Second, the ability for citizens to get involved in and have control
over the political process, independently increases well-being.
American psychologist Barry Schwartz argues in his book The Paradox of Choice that too many consumer and lifestyle choices can produce anxiety and unhappiness due to analysis paralysis and raised expectations of satisfaction.
Religious diversity
National cross-sectional data suggest an inverse relationship between religious diversity and happiness, possibly by facilitating more bonding (and less bridging) social capital.
Happiness and leisure
Much of the research regarding happiness and leisure relies on subjective well-being
(SWB) as an appropriate measure of happiness. Research has demonstrated
a wide variety of contributing and resulting factors in the
relationship between leisure and happiness. These include psychological
mechanisms, and the types and characteristics of leisure activities that
result in the greatest levels of subjective happiness. Specifically,
leisure may trigger five core psychological mechanisms including
detachment-recovery from work, autonomy in leisure, mastery of leisure
activities, meaning-making in leisure activities, and social affiliation
in leisure (DRAMMA).
Leisure activities that are physical, relational, and performed
outdoors are correlated with greater feelings of satisfaction with free
time.
Research across 33 different countries shows that individuals who feel
they strengthen social relationships and work on personal development
during leisure time are happier than others.
Furthermore, shopping, reading books, attending cultural events,
getting together with relatives, listening to music and attending
sporting events is associated with higher levels of happiness. Spending
time on the internet or watching TV is not associated with higher levels
of happiness as compared to these other activities.
Research has shown that culture influences how we measure
happiness and leisure. While SWB is a commonly used measure of happiness
in North America and Europe, this may not be the case internationally. Quality of life
(QOL) may be a better measure of happiness and leisure in Asian
countries, especially Korea. Countries such as China and Japan may
require a different measurement of happiness, as societal differences
may influence the concept of happiness (i.e. economic variables, cultural practices, and social networks) beyond what QOL is able to measure.
There seem to be some differences in leisure preference
cross-culturally. Within the Croatian culture, family related leisure
activities may enhance SWB across a large spectrum of ages ranging from
adolescent to older adults, in both women and men. Active socializing
and visiting cultural events are also associated with high levels of SWB
across varying age and gender.
Italians seem to prefer social conceptions of leisure as opposed to
individualistic conceptions. Although different groups of individuals
may prefer varying types and amount of leisure activity, this
variability is likely due to the differing motivations and goals that an
individual intends to fulfill with their leisure time.
Research suggests that specific leisure interventions enhance feelings of SWB. This is both a top-down and bottom-up effect, in that leisure satisfaction causally affects SWB, and SWB causally affects leisure satisfaction.
This bi-directional effect is stronger in retired individuals than in
working individuals. Furthermore, it appears that satisfaction with our
leisure at least partially explains the relationship between our
engagement in leisure and our SWB.
Broadly speaking, researchers classify leisure into active (e.g.
volunteering, socializing, sports and fitness) and passive leisure (e.g.
watching television and listening to the radio).
Among older adults, passive leisure activities and personal leisure
activities (e.g. sleeping, eating, and bathing) correlate with higher
levels of SWB and feelings of relaxation than active leisure activities.
Thus, although significant evidence has demonstrated that active
leisure is associated with higher levels of SWB, or happiness, this may
not be the case with older populations.
Both regular and irregular involvement in sports leisure can
result in heightened SWB. Serious, or systematic involvement in certain
leisure activities, such as taekwondo, correlates with personal growth and a sense of happiness.
Additionally, more irregular (e.g. seasonal) sports activities, such as
skiing, are also correlated with high SWB. Furthermore, the
relationship between pleasure and skiing is thought to be caused in part
by a sense of flow and involvement with the activity.
Leisure activities, such as meeting with friends, participating in
sports, and going on vacation trips, positively correlate with life
satisfaction.
It may also be true that going on a vacation makes our lives seem
better, but does not necessarily make us happier in the long term.
Research regarding vacationing or taking a holiday trip is mixed.
Although the reported effects are mostly small, some evidence points to
higher levels of SWB, or happiness, after taking a holiday.
Economic security
Poverty alleviation are associated with happier populations. According
to the latest systematic review of the economic literature on life
satisfaction: Volatile or high inflation is bad for a population's
well-being, particularly those with a right-wing political orientation.
That suggests the impact of disruptions to economic security are in
part mediated or modified by beliefs about economic security.
Political stability
The Voxeu
analysis of the economic determinants of happiness found that life
satisfaction explains the largest share of an existing government's vote
share, followed by economic growth, which itself explains six times as
much as employment and twice as much as inflation.
Economic freedom
Individualistic societies have happier populations.
Institutes of economic freedom are associated with increases wealth
inequality but does not necessarily contribute to decreases in aggregate
well-being or subjective well-being at the population level. In fact, income inequality enhances global well-being.
There is some debate over whether living in poor neighbours make one
happier. And, living among rich neighbours can dull the happiness that
comes from wealth. This is purported to work by way of an upward or
downward comparison effect (Keeping up with the Joneses).
The balance of evidence is trending in favour of the hypothesis that
living in poor neighbourhoods makes one less happy, and living in rich
neighbourhoods actually makes one happier, in the United States. While
social status matters, a balance of factors like amenities, safe areas,
well maintained housing, turn the tide in favour of the argument that
richer neighbours are happier neighbours.
Democracy
"The
right to participate in the political process, measured by the extent
of direct democratic rights across regions, is strongly correlated with
subjective well-being (Frey and Stutzer, 2002) ... a potential mechanism that explains this relationship is the perception of procedural fairness and social mobility." Institutions and well-being, democracy and federalism are associated with a happier population. Correspondingly, political engagement and activism have associated health benefits.
On the other hand, some non democratic countries such as China and Saudi
Arabia top the Ipsos list of countries where the citizenry is most
happy with their government's direction.
That suggests that voting preferences may not translate well into
overall satisfaction with the government's direction. In any case, both
of these factors revealed preference and domain specific satisfaction
rather than overall subjective well being.
Economic development
Historically, economists thought economic growth was unrelated to population level well-being, a phenomenon labelled the Easterlin paradox. More robust research has identified that there is a link between economic development and the wellbeing of the population.
A 2017 meta-analysis shows that the impact of infrastructure expenditure on economic growth varies considerable.
So, one cannot assume an infrastructure project will yield welfare
benefits. The paper doesn't investigate or elaborate on any modifiable
variables that might predict the value of a project. However, government
spending on roads and primary industries is the best value target for
transport spending, according to a 2013 meta-analysis.
7%+/−3% per annum discount rates are typically applied as the discount rate on public infrastructure projects in Australia. Smaller real discount rates are used internationally to calculate the social return on investment by governments.
Alternative approach: economic consequences of happiness
While
the mainstream happiness economics has focused on identifying the
determinants of happiness, an alternative approach in the discipline
examines instead what are the economic consequences of happiness.
Happiness may act as a determinant of economic outcomes: it increases
productivity, predicts one's future income and affects labour market
performance. There is a growing number of studies justifying the so-called "happy-productive worker" thesis. The positive and causal impact of happiness on an individual's productivity has been established in experimental studies.
Happiness economics and indices timeline
The
idea that happiness is important to a society is not new. Many other
prominent intellectuals, philosophers and political leaders throughout
history, including Aristotle, Confucius, and Plato, incorporated happiness into their work.
Thomas Jefferson put the "pursuit of happiness" on the same level as life and liberty in the United States' Declaration of Independence. Jeremy Bentham believed that public policy should attempt to maximize happiness, and he even attempted to estimate a "hedonic calculus".
However, the American ruling philosophy protects the right of
individuals to seek their own happiness, but does not place an equal
responsibility for the citizens' happiness on the government. In the
United States, there is no explicit policy that requires the rulers to
develop the physical and mental well-being of the citizens or hold the
government agencies accountable for their performance against specific
measures or metrics of well-being. Until the 1972 there was no formal
government policy, anywhere in the world, that placed happiness and
well-being as a main criterion for public policy decision making.
The following is a chronological list of happiness economics and well-being indices:
1972 – Bhutan's former king, Jigme Singye Wangchuck, introduced the Gross National Happiness (GNH) philosophy and its four development pillars at an international conference.
2005 – Med Jones of the International Institute of Management introduced the first GNH Index and Global GNH Index Survey. The GNH Index, also known as Gross National Well-being
(GNW) Index framework served as the first integrated objective
(economic) and subjective (happiness) socioeconomic development
framework. Prior the GNH Index, there were few development indices that
improved upon the gross domestic product (GDP), but did not measure
happiness. For example, the Genuine Progress Indicator
was focused on the environmental cost of economic development, then
later (in 2006) it was updated to include similar measures to the GNH
Index. Another development index is the Human Development Index (HDI) that originally focused on literacy and education but also did not measure happiness.
The HDI now measures three basic dimensions of human development,
health (as measured by life expectancy at birth), overall knowledge
level (as measured by the literacy rate), and standard of living (as
measured by GDP per capita for a given year). Among the criticisms of
the HDI is the complaint that it is a mixture of stock measures (life
expectancy at birth and literacy rate) and a flow measure (GDP per
capita for a given year). To overcome this criticism, Hou, Walsh, and
Zhang (2015) proposed a new index called HDIF (Human Development Index
Flow), in which they replaced life expectancy at birth by the under-five
mortality rate (for a given year), and they also replaced the literacy
rate by the gross primary school enrollment ratio for a given year).
They calculated both the HDI and the HDIF for many countries and found
that "the HDIF and the HDI tend to converge for wealthy countries and
diverge for poor countries, especially those with low HDI rankings". The
development performance of poor countries improved using the HDIF while
the performance of the wealthy countries declined.
2006 – The Genuine Progress Indicator was updated from a green measurement system to a broader concept that included quantitative measurement of well-being and happiness.
The new measure is motivated by the philosophy of the GNH and the same
notion of that subjective measures like well-being are more relevant and
important than more objective measures like consumption. It is not measured directly, but only by means of the factors which are believed to lead to it.
2007 – Thailand releases Green and Happiness Index (GHI).
2008 – French President Nicolas Sarkozy
launched a Happiness Initiative similar to GNH, calling for the
inclusion of happiness and well-being among the criteria for national
governance policies. He commissioned three prominent economists, Joseph
Stiglitz (USA), Amartya Sen (India), Jean-Paul Fitoussi (France), to
publish a report calling for a global "statistical system which goes
beyond commercial activity to measure personal well-being." Later it was
described as gross domestic happiness (GDH). The GDH Index is similar to the GNH Index of 2005.
2009 – In the United States, the Gallup poll system launched the happiness survey collecting data on national scale.
The Gallup Well-Being Index was modeled after the GNH Index framework
of 2005. The Well-Being Index score is an average of six sub-indexes
which measure life evaluation, emotional health, work environment,
physical health, healthy behaviors, and access to basic necessities. In
October 2009, the US scored 66.1/100.
2010 – The concept was taken seriously, as the Centre for Bhutan Studies, under the leadership of Karma Ura, developed a sophisticated survey instrument to measure the population's general level of well-being.
Two Canadians, Michael and Martha Pennock played a major role in
developing the Bhutanese survey, which took a six- to seven-hour
interview to complete. They developed a shorter international version of
the survey which has been used in their home region of Victoria BC as
well as in Brazil. The Pennocks also collaborated with Ura in the
production of a policy lens which is used by the Bhutanese GNH
Commission for anticipating the impact of policy initiatives upon the
levels of GNH in Bhutan.
2010 – The Center for Bhutan Studies further defined the original
four pillars with greater specificity into eight general contributors
to happiness—physical, mental and spiritual health; time-balance; social
and community vitality; cultural vitality; education; living standards;
good governance; and ecological vitality. The Bhutan GNH Index.
2010 – The Oxford Poverty and Human Development Initiative OPHI at the University of Oxford in UK, launched the Multidimensional Poverty Index
(MPI) for the United Nations Development Programme, (UNDP). Similar to
the GNH Index of 2005, OPHI promotes collection and analysis of data on
five dimensions including Quality of work, Empowerment, Physical safety,
Ability to go about without shame, Psychological wellbeing.
2011 – UN General Assembly Resolution 65/309, titled "Happiness: towards a holistic approach to development."
2011 – The Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) launched "Better Life Index" (BLI).
2011 – The United Nations released the World Happiness Report.
2011 – Canadian Index of Wellbeing Network (CIW Network) released The Canadian Index of Wellbeing (CIW).
2011 – The Israeli newspaper Haaretz
published an article suggesting that western GDP economics is an
incomplete development model and called for the adoption of Bhutan's GNH
philosophy and Jones' GNH Index in Israel.
2011 – Chuluun Togtokh criticized the HDI in an article published in Nature,
calling for a revised HDI, writing that "The revised index should
include each nation's per capita carbon emissions, and so become a Human
Sustainable Development Index (HSDI)."
Bravo (2014) provided details of how the HSDI was computed and proposed
an amended HSDI by including the proportion of forested area in each
country. He argued that this proposed indicator "represents an
important measure of the capacity of natural system to provide
fundamental ecological services."
2012 – In a report prepared for the US Congressman Hansen Clarke, R, researchers Ben Beachy and Juston Zorn, at John F. Kennedy School of Government in Harvard University,
recommended that "the Congress should prescribe the broad parameters of
new, carefully designed supplemental national indicators; it should
launch a bipartisan commission of experts to address unresolved
methodological issues, and include alternative indicators." They
proposed that the government can use the survey results to see which
well-being dimensions are least satisfied and which districts and
demographic groups are most deficient, so as to allocate resources
accordingly. The report list the Gross National Happiness Index and its
seven measurement area as one of the main frameworks to consider.
2012 – Professor Peter T. Coleman, a director of the International Center for Cooperation and Conflict Resolution at Columbia University, suggested that Jones' GNH Index initiative could inform the Global Peace Index Initiative GPI.
2012 – South Korea launched Happiness Index citing the GNH Index framework.
2012 – The government of Goa, India, published a strategy for socioeconomic development citing the GNH Index as a model for measuring happiness.
2012 – The city of Seattle in Washington, launched its own happiness index initiative, emphasizing measures similar to the GNH Index.
2013 – The Social Progress Index SPI was launched by Michael Porter.
2013 – The president of Singapore, Tony Tan, proposed that in addition to building up substantial financial reserves, Singapore needed to focus on building up its "social reserves", a concept that appears to have parallels to GNH.
2013 – Economist Karol Jan Borowiecki motivates that well-being
indices can be obtained from the way people communicate, as is
established in psychology, and compiles the first well-being indices
covering the life-time of a person.
2013 – A joint commission led by the Conseil économique et
social, the Conseil supérieur pour un développement durable and the
Observatoire de la Compétitivité introduces a set of indicators
measuring the quality of life in Luxembourg. The conclusions of the
commission are summarised in a document titled "Projet PIBien-être", which identifies 64 indicators belonging to 11 different domains to assess quality of life in Luxembourg.
2014 – The government of Dubai launched its localized Happiness Index to measure the public's contentment and satisfaction with different government services.
2014 – The United Kingdom launched its own well-being and happiness statistics.
2015 – Within the "Projet PIBien-être"
launched in 2013, STATEC (National Institute of Statistics and Economic
Studies of the Grand Duchy of Luxembourg) presents a preliminary
analysis of the "Luxembourgish Index of Well-being" (LIW), a first
proposal of synthetic indicator measuring the quality of life in
Luxembourg.
The presentation entitled "Preliminary Assessment of Quality of Life in
Luxembourg" was delivered by Marcin Piekałkiewicz on 16 December 2015.
2017 – The Minderoo Foundation launched the Global Slavery Index,
providing a map of the estimated prevalence of modern slavery. The
information allows an objective comparison and assessment of both the
problem and adequacy of the response in 167 countries.
Related studies
The Satisfaction with Life Index
is an attempt to show the average self-reported happiness in different
nations. This is an example of a recent trend to use direct measures of
happiness, such as surveys asking people how happy they are, as an
alternative to traditional measures of policy success such as GDP or
GNP. Some studies suggest that happiness can be measured effectively. The Inter-American Development Bank (IDB), published in November 2008 a major study on happiness economics in Latin America and the Caribbean.
In 2013, John Helliwell, Richard Layard and Jeffery Sachs
compiled a treatise under the title "World Happiness report 2013" to
elaborate on the measurement of popular happiness in different countries
thereby adding to the wealth of happiness data available while
specifically discussing the issues of measurement, explanation and
policy. Global and Regional Happiness Levels are explained in terms of
10 regional groupings of countries based on happiness data available for
the year 2010-2012. The happiness level is explained as a function of
GDP per capita, social support, and healthy life expectancy, freedom to
make life choices, generosity and perceptions of corruption.
There are also several examples of measures that includes self-reported happiness as one variable. Happy Life Years, a concept brought by Dutch sociologist Ruut Veenhoven, combines self-reported happiness with life expectancy. The Happy Planet Index combines it with life expectancy and ecological footprint.
Gross National Happiness (GNH) is a concept introduced by the King of Bhutan in 1972 as an alternative to GDP. Several countries have already developed or are in the process of developing such an index.
Bhutan's index has led that country to limit the amount of
deforestation it will allow and to require that all tourists to its
nation must spend US$200 Allegedly, low-budget tourism and deforestation lead to unhappiness.
After the military coup of 2006, Thailand also instituted an index. The stated promise of the new Prime Minister Surayud Chulanont is to make the Thai people not only richer but happier as well. Much like GDP results, Thailand releases monthly GNH data. The Thai GNH index is based on a 1–10 scale with 10 being the most happy. As of May 13, 2007, the Thai GNH measured 5.1 points.
The index uses poll data from the population surveying various
satisfaction factors such as, security, public utilities, good
governance, trade, social justice, allocation of resources, education
and community problems.
Australia, China, France, and the United Kingdom are also coming up with indexes to measure national happiness. The UK began to measure national wellbeing in 2012. North Korea also announced an international Happiness Index in 2011 through Korean Central Television. North Korea itself came in second, behind #1 China [DJS -- If you don't find this pretty funny, you have no sense of humor].
Canada released the Canadian Index of Wellbeing (CIW) in 2011 to track
changes in wellbeing. The CIW has adopted the following working
definition of wellbeing: The presence of the highest possible quality of
life in its full breadth of expression focused on but not necessarily
exclusive to: good living standards, robust health, a sustainable
environment, vital communities, an educated populace, balanced time use,
high levels of democratic participation, and access to and
participation in leisure and culture.
Ecuador's and Bolivia's new constitutions state the indigenous concept of "good life" ("buen vivir" in Spanish, "sumak kawsay" in Quichua, and "suma qamaña" in Aymara) as the goal of sustainable development.
Neoclassical economics
Neoclassical, as well as classical economics, are not subsumed under the term happiness economics
although the original goal was to increase the happiness of the people.
Classical and neoclassical economics are stages in the development of welfare economics
and are characterized by mathematical modeling. Happiness economics
represents a radical break with this tradition. The measurement of subjective happiness respectively life satisfaction by means of survey research
across nations and time (in addition to objective measures like
lifespan, wealth, security etc.) marks the beginning of happiness
economics.
Criticism
Some have suggested that establishing happiness as a metric is only meant to serve political goals. Recently there has been concern that happiness research could be used to advance authoritarian aims.
As a result, some participants at a happiness conference in Rome have
suggested that happiness research should not be used as a matter of
public policy but rather used to inform individuals.
Even on the individual level there is discussion on how much
effect external forces can have on happiness. Less than 3% of an
individual's level of happiness comes from external sources such as
employment, education level, marital status, and socioeconomic status. To go along with this, four of the Big Five Personality Traits are substantially associated with life satisfaction, openness to experience is not associated. Having high levels of internal locus of control lead to higher reported levels of happiness.
Even when happiness can be affected by external sources, it has high hedonic adaptation,
some specific events such as an increase in income, disability,
unemployment, and loss (bereavement) only have short-term (about a year)
effects on a person's overall happiness and after a while happiness may
return to levels similar to unaffected peers.
What has the most influence over happiness are internal factors
such as genetics, personality traits, and internal locus of control. It
is theorized that 50% of the variation in happiness levels is from
genetic sources and is known as the genetic set point. The genetic set
point is assumed to be stable over time, fixed, and immune to influence
or control. This goes along with findings that well-being surveys have a naturally positive baseline.
With such strong internal forces on happiness it is hard to have
an effect on a person's happiness externally. This in turn lends itself
back to the idea that establishing a happiness metric is only for
political gain and has little other use. To support this even further
it is believed that a country aggregate level of SWB can account for
more variance in government vote share than standard macroeconomic
variables, such as income and employment.
Technical criticism
According
to Bond and Lang (2018) the results are skewed due to the fact that the
respondents have to "round" their true happiness to the scale of, e.g.,
3 or 7 alternatives (e.g., very happy, pretty happy, not too happy).
This "rounding error" may cause a less happy group seem more happy, in
the average. This would not be the case if the happiness of both groups
would be normally distributed with the same variance, but that is
usually not the case, based on their results. For some not-implausible
log-normal assumptions on the scale, typical results can be reversed to
the opposite results.
They also show that the "reporting function" seems to be
different for different groups and even for the same individual at
different times. For example, when a person becomes disabled, they soon
start to lower their threshold for a given answer (e.g., "pretty
happy"). That is, they give a higher answer than they would have given
at the same happiness state before becoming disabled.