A tariff is a tax on imports or exports between sovereign states. It is a form of regulation of foreign trade and a policy that taxes foreign products to encourage or safeguard domestic industry. Traditionally, states have used them as a source of income. Now, they are among the most widely used instruments of protectionism, along with import and export quotas.
Tariffs can be fixed (a constant sum per unit of imported goods or a percentage of the price) or variable (the amount varies according to the price). Taxing items coming into the country means people are less likely to buy them as they become more expensive. The intention is that they buy local products instead – boosting the country's economy. Tariffs therefore provide an incentive to develop production and replace imports with domestic products. Tariffs are meant to reduce pressure from foreign competition and reduce the trade deficit. They have historically been justified as a means to protect infant industries and to allow import substitution industrialization. Tariffs may also be used to rectify artificially low prices for certain imported goods, due to 'dumping', export subsidies or currency manipulation.
There is near unanimous consensus among economists that tariffs have a negative effect on economic growth and economic welfare while free trade and the reduction of trade barriers has a positive effect on economic growth. However, liberalization of trade can cause significant and unequally distributed losses, and the economic dislocation of workers in import-competing sectors.
Etymology
The origin of tariff is the Italian word tariffa translated as "list of prices, book of rates", which is likely derived from the Arabic ta'rif تعريف meaning "notification" or "inventory of fees to be paid".
History
Great Britain
At
the beginning of the 19th century, Britain's average tariff on
manufactured goods was roughly 51 percent, the highest of any major
nation in Europe. And even after Britain embraced free trade in most
goods, it continued to tightly regulate trade in strategic capital
goods, such as the machinery for the mass production of textiles.
In 1800, Great Britain with about 10% of the European population,
provided 29% of all pig iron produced in Europe, a proportion that
reached 45% in 1830; industrial production per capita was even more
significant: in 1830 it was 250% higher than in the rest of Europe
compared to 110% in 1800.
Tariffs were reduced in 1833 and the Corn Laws were repealed
in 1846, which amounted to free trade in food. (The Corn Laws were
passed in 1815 to restrict wheat imports and guarantee British farmers'
incomes ). This devastated Britain's old rural economy but began to
mitigate the effects of Great Famine in Ireland.
On 15 June 1903, the Secretary of State for Foreign Affairs, the Marquess of Lansdowne
made a speech in the House of Lords defending fiscal retaliation
against countries with high tariffs and whose governments subsidised
products for sale in Britain (known as 'bounty-fed products', also
called dumping).
The retaliation was to be done by threatening to impose tariffs in
response against that country's goods. His Liberal Unionists had split
from the Liberals, who promoted Free Trade, and the speech was a landmark in the group's slide towards Protectionism.
Landsdowne argued that threatening retaliatory tariffs was similar to
getting respect in a room of armed men by showing a big revolver (his
exact words were "a rather larger revolver than everybody else's"). The
"Big Revolver" became a catchphrase of the day, often used in speeches
and cartoons
United States
Before the new Constitution took effect in 1788, the Congress could
not levy taxes—it sold land or begged money from the states. The new
national government needed revenue and decided to depend upon a tax on
imports with the Tariff of 1789. The policy of the U.S. before 1860 was low tariffs "for revenue only" (since duties continued to fund the national government). A high tariff was attempted in 1828 but the South denounced it as a "Tariff of Abominations" and it almost caused a rebellion in South Carolina until it was lowered.
The policy from 1860 to 1933 was usually high protective tariffs
(apart from 1913–21) After 1890, the tariff on wool did affect an
important industry, but otherwise the tariffs were designed to keep
American wages high. The conservative Republican tradition, typified by William McKinley was a high tariff, while the Democrats typically called for a lower tariff to help consumers.
Protectionism was an American tradition: according to Paul
Bairoch, the United States was "the homeland and bastion of modern
protectionism" since the end of the 18th century and until after World
War II.
From 1846 to 1861, during which American tariffs were lowered but this
was followed by a series of recessions and the 1857 panic, which
eventually led to higher demands for tariffs than President James
Buchanan, signed in 1861 (Morrill Tariff).
Between 1816 and the end of the Second World War, the United States had
one of the highest average tariff rates on manufactured imports in the
world. According to economic historian Douglas Irwin, a common myth
about United States trade policy is that low tariffs harmed American
manufacturers in the early 19th century and then that high tariffs made
the United States into a great industrial power in the late 19th
century. A review by the Economist of Irwin's 2017 book Clashing over Commerce: A History of US Trade Policy notes:
Political dynamics would lead people to see a link between tariffs and the economic cycle that was not there. A boom would generate enough revenue for tariffs to fall, and when the bust came pressure would build to raise them again. By the time that happened, the economy would be recovering, giving the impression that tariff cuts caused the crash and the reverse generated the recovery. Mr Irwin also methodically debunks the idea that protectionism made America a great industrial power, a notion believed by some to offer lessons for developing countries today. As its share of global manufacturing powered from 23% in 1870 to 36% in 1913, the admittedly high tariffs of the time came with a cost, estimated at around 0.5% of GDP in the mid-1870s. In some industries, they might have sped up development by a few years. But American growth during its protectionist period was more to do with its abundant resources and openness to people and ideas.
In the 19th century, statesmen such as Senator Henry Clay continued Hamilton's themes within the Whig Party under the name "American System.[17][full citation needed] Before 1860 they were always defeated by the low-tariff Democrats.
During the American Civil War (1861-1865), agrarian interests in
the South were opposed to any protection, while manufacturing interests
in the North wanted to maintain it. The war marked the triumph of the
protectionists of the industrial states of the North over the free
traders of the South. Abraham Lincoln was a protectionist like Henry
Clay of the Whig Party, who advocated the "American system" based on
infrastructure development and protectionism. In 1847, he declared:
"Give us a protective tariff, and we will have the greatest nation on
earth". Once elected, Lincoln raised industrial tariffs and after the
war, tariffs remained at or above wartime levels. High tariffs were a
policy designed to encourage rapid industrialisation and protect the
high American wage rates.
The Democrats called for low tariffs help poor consumers, but
they always failed until 1913. The Republican Party, which is heir to
the Whigs, makes protectionism a central theme in its electoral
platforms. According to the party, it is right to favour domestic
producers and tax foreigners and consumers of imported luxury products.
Republicans prioritize the protection function, while the need to
provide revenue to the federal budget is only a secondary objective.
In the early 1860s, Europe and the United States pursued
completely different trade policies. The 1860s were a period of growing
protectionism in the United States, while the European free trade phase
lasted from 1860 to 1892. The tariff average rate on imports of
manufactured goods was in 1875 from 40% to 50% in the United States
against 9% to 12% in continental Europe at the height of free trade.
Milton Friedman
held the opinion that the Smoot–Hawley tariff of 1930 did not cause the
Great Depression, instead he blamed the lack of sufficient action on
the part of the Federal Reserve. Douglas A. Irwin wrote: "most
economists, both liberal and conservative, doubt that Smoot–Hawley
played much of a role in the subsequent contraction".
Tariffs and the Great Depression
Most economists hold the opinion that the US Tariff Act did not greatly worsen the great depression:
Peter Temin,
an economist at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, explained
that a tariff is an expansionary policy, like a devaluation as it
diverts demand from foreign to home producers. He noted that exports
were 7 percent of GNP in 1929, they fell by 1.5 percent of 1929 GNP in
the next two years and the fall was offset by the increase in domestic
demand from tariff. He concluded that contrary the popular argument,
contractionary effect of the tariff was small.
William Bernstein wrote: "Between 1929 and 1932, real GDP fell 17
percent worldwide, and by 26 percent in the United States, but most
economic historians now believe that only a miniscule part of that huge
loss of both world GDP and the United States’ GDP can be ascribed to the
tariff wars. .. At the time of Smoot-Hawley’s passage, trade volume
accounted for only about 9 percent of world economic output. Had all
international trade been eliminated, and had no domestic use for the
previously exported goods been found, world GDP would have fallen by the
same amount — 9 percent. Between 1930 and 1933, worldwide trade volume
fell off by one-third to one-half. Depending on how the falloff is
measured, this computes to 3 to 5 percent of world GDP, and these losses
were partially made up by more expensive domestic goods. Thus, the
damage done could not possibly have exceeded 1 or 2 percent of world GDP
— nowhere near the 17 percent falloff seen during the Great
Depression... The inescapable conclusion: contrary to public perception,
Smoot-Hawley did not cause, or even significantly deepen, the Great
Depression,"
Nobel laureate Maurice Allais
argued: 'First, most of the trade contraction occurred between January
1930 and July 1932, before most protectionist measures were introduced,
except for the limited measures applied by the United States in the
summer of 1930. It was therefore the collapse of international liquidity
that caused the contraction of trade[8], not customs tariffs'.
Russia
Russia
adopted more protectionist trade measures in 2013 than any other
country, making it the world leader in protectionism. It alone
introduced 20% of protectionist measures worldwide and one-third of
measures in the G20 countries. Russia's protectionist policies include
tariff measures, import restrictions, sanitary measures, and direct
subsidies to local companies. For example, the state supported several
economic sectors such as agriculture, space, automotive, electronics,
chemistry, and energy.
In recent years, the policy of import substitution due to
tariffs, i.e. the replacement of imported products by domestic products,
has been considered a success because it has enabled Russia to increase
its domestic production and save several billion dollars. Russia has
been able to reduce its imports and launch an emerging and increasingly
successful domestic production in almost all industrial sectors. The
most important results have been achieved in the agriculture and food
processing, automotive, chemical, pharmaceutical, aviation and naval
sectors.
From 2014, customs duties were applied on imported products in
the food sector. Russia has reduced its food imports while domestic
production has increased considerably. The cost of food imports has
dropped from $60 billion in 2014 to $20 billion in 2017 and the country
enjoys record cereal production. Russia has strengthened its position on
the world food market and the country has become food self-sufficient.
In the fisheries, fruit and vegetable sector, domestic production has
increased sharply, imports have declined significantly and the trade
balance (difference between exports and imports) has improved. In the
second quarter of 2017, agricultural exports are expected to exceed
imports, making Russia a net exporter for the first time.
India
From 2017, as part of the promotion of its "Make in India" programme
to stimulate and protect domestic manufacturing industry and to combat
current account deficits, India has introduced tariffs on several
electronic products and "non-essential items". This concerns items
imported from countries such as China and South Korea. For example,
India's national solar energy programme favours domestic producers by
requiring the use of Indian-made solar cells.
Armenia
The
Republic of Armenia, a country located in Western Asia, established its
custom service on January 4, 1992, as directed by the Armenian
President. On January 2, 2015, Armenia was given access to the Eurasian
Customs Union, which is led by the Russian Federation and the EAEU; this
resulted in an increased number of import tariffs. Armenia does not
currently have export taxes; in addition, it does not declare temporary
imports duties and credit on government imports or pursuant to other
international assistance imports.
Customs duty
A customs duty or due is the indirect tax levied on the import or export of goods in international trade. In economic sense, a duty is also a kind of consumption tax. A duty levied on goods being imported is referred to as an import duty. Similarly, a duty levied on exports is called an export duty. A tariff, which is actually a list of commodities along with the leviable rate (amount) of customs duty, is popularly referred to as a customs duty.
Calculation of customs duty
Customs duty is calculated on the determination of the assessable value in case of those items for which the duty is levied ad valorem. This is often the transaction value unless a customs officer determines assessable value in accordance with the Harmonized System. For certain items like petroleum and alcohol, customs duty is realized at a specific rate applied to the volume of the import or export consignments.
Harmonized System of Nomenclature
For the purpose of assessment of customs duty, products are given an identification code that has come to be known as the Harmonized System code. This code was developed by the World Customs Organization based in Brussels. A Harmonized System code may be from four to ten digits. For example, 17.03 is the HS code for molasses from the extraction or refining of sugar. However, within 17.03, the number 17.03.90 stands for "Molasses (Excluding Cane Molasses)".
Introduction of Harmonized System code in 1990s has largely replaced the Standard International Trade Classification
(SITC), though SITC remains in use for statistical purposes. In drawing
up the national tariff, the revenue departments often specifies the
rate of customs duty with reference to the HS code of the product. In
some countries and customs unions, 6-digit HS codes are locally extended
to 8 digits or 10 digits for further tariff discrimination: for example
the European Union uses its 8-digit CN (Combined Nomenclature) and 10-digit TARIC codes.
Customs authority
A customs
authority in each country is responsible for collecting taxes on the
import into or export of goods out of the country. Normally the customs
authority, operating under national law, is authorized to examine cargo
in order to ascertain actual description, specification volume or
quantity, so that the assessable value and the rate of duty may be
correctly determined and applied.
Evasion
Evasion of customs duties takes place mainly in two ways. In one, the
trader under-declares the value so that the assessable value is lower
than actual. In a similar vein, a trader can evade customs duty by
understatement of quantity or volume of the product of trade. A trader
may also evade duty by misrepresenting traded goods, categorizing goods
as items which attract lower customs duties. The evasion of customs duty
may take place with or without the collaboration of customs officials. Evasion of customs duty does not necessarily constitute smuggling.
Duty-free goods
Many countries allow a traveler to bring goods into the country duty-free. These goods may be bought at ports and airports
or sometimes within one country without attracting the usual government
taxes and then brought into another country duty-free. Some countries
impose allowances
which limit the number or value of duty-free items that one person can
bring into the country. These restrictions often apply to tobacco, wine, spirits, cosmetics, gifts and souvenirs. Often foreign diplomats and UN officials are entitled to duty-free goods. Duty-free goods are imported and stocked in what is called a bonded warehouse.
Duty calculation for companies in real life
With
many methods and regulations, businesses at times struggle to manage
the duties. In addition to difficulties in calculations, there are
challenges in analyzing duties; and to opt for duty free options like
using a bonded warehouse.
Companies use Enterprise Resource Planning
(ERP) software to calculate duties automatically to, on the one hand,
avoid error-prone manual work on duty regulations and formulas and, on
the other hand, manage and analyze historically paid duties. Moreover,
ERP software offers an option for customs warehouses to save duty and
VAT payments. In addition, duty deferment and suspension can also be
taken into consideration.
Economic analysis
Neoclassical economic theorists tend to view tariffs as distortions to the free market.
Typical analyses find that tariffs tend to benefit domestic producers
and government at the expense of consumers, and that the net welfare
effects of a tariff on the importing country are negative. Normative
judgments often follow from these findings, namely that it may be
disadvantageous for a country to artificially shield an industry from
world markets and that it might be better to allow a collapse to take
place. Opposition to all tariff aims to reduce tariffs and to avoid
countries discriminating between differing countries when applying
tariffs. The diagrams at right show the costs and benefits of imposing a
tariff on a good in the domestic economy.
Imposing an import tariff has the following effects, shown in the
first diagram in a hypothetical domestic market for televisions:
- Price rises from world price Pw to higher tariff price Pt.
- Quantity demanded by domestic consumers falls from C1 to C2, a movement along the demand curve due to higher price.
- Domestic suppliers are willing to supply Q2 rather than Q1, a movement along the supply curve due to the higher price, so the quantity imported falls from C1-Q1 to C2-Q2.
- Consumer surplus (the area under the demand curve but above price) shrinks by areas A+B+C+D, as domestic consumers face higher prices and consume lower quantities.
- Producer surplus (the area above the supply curve but below price) increases by area A, as domestic producers shielded from international competition can sell more of their product at a higher price.
- Government tax revenue is the import quantity (C2-Q2) times the tariff price (Pw - Pt), shown as area C.
- Areas B and D are deadweight losses, surplus formerly captured by consumers that now is lost to all parties.
The overall change in welfare = Change in Consumer Surplus + Change
in Producer Surplus + Change in Government Revenue = (-A-B-C-D) + A + C =
-B-D. The final state after imposition of the tariff is indicated in
the second diagram, with overall welfare reduced by the areas labeled
"societal losses", which correspond to areas B and D in the first
diagram. The losses to domestic consumers are greater than the combined
benefits to domestic producers and government.
That tariffs overall reduce welfare is not a controversial topic
among economists. For example, the University of Chicago surveyed about
40 leading economists in March 2018 asking whether "Imposing new U.S.
tariffs on steel and aluminum will improve Americans'welfare." About
two-thirds strongly disagreed with the statement, while one third
disagreed. None agreed or strongly agreed. Several commented that such
tariffs would help a few Americans at the expense of many.
This is consistent with the explanation provided above, which is that
losses to domestic consumers outweigh gains to domestic producers and
government, by the amount of deadweight losses.
Tariffs are more inefficient than consumption taxes.
Optimal tariff
For economic efficiency, free trade is often the best policy, however levying a tariff is sometimes second best.
A tariff is called an optimal tariff if it is set to maximize the welfare of the country imposing the tariff. It is a tariff derived by the intersection between the trade indifference curve of that country and the offer curve of another country. In this case, the welfare of the other country grows worse simultaneously, thus the policy is a kind of beggar thy neighbor policy. If the offer curve of the other country is a line through the origin point, the original country is in the condition of a small country, so any tariff worsens the welfare of the original country.
It is possible to levy a tariff as a political policy choice, and to consider a theoretical optimum tariff rate.
However, imposing an optimal tariff will often lead to the foreign
country increasing their tariffs as well, leading to a loss of welfare
in both countries. When countries impose tariffs on each other, they
will reach a position off the contract curve, meaning that both countries' welfare could be increased by reducing tariffs.
Political analysis
The tariff has been used as a political tool to establish an independent nation; for example, the United States Tariff Act of 1789,
signed specifically on July 4, was called the "Second Declaration of
Independence" by newspapers because it was intended to be the economic
means to achieve the political goal of a sovereign and independent
United States.
The political impact of tariffs is judged depending on the political perspective; for example the 2002 United States steel tariff
imposed a 30% tariff on a variety of imported steel products for a
period of three years and American steel producers supported the tariff.
Tariffs can emerge as a political issue prior to an election. In the leadup to the 2007 Australian Federal election, the Australian Labor Party announced it would undertake a review of Australian car tariffs if elected. The Liberal Party made a similar commitment, while independent candidate Nick Xenophon announced his intention to introduce tariff-based legislation as "a matter of urgency".
Unpopular tariffs are known to have ignited social unrest, for example the 1905 meat riots in Chile that developed in protest against tariffs applied to the cattle imports from Argentina.
Arguments in favor of tariffs
Protection of infant industry
In the 19th century, Alexander Hamilton and the economist Friedrich List defended the benefits of "educator protectionism" as a necessary means of protecting infant industries.
Protectionism would be necessary in the short term for a country to
start industrialization away from competition from more advanced foreign
industries, under which pressure it could succumb at the first stage of
the process. As a result, they benefit from greater freedom of
manoeuvre and greater certainty regarding their profitability and future
development. The protectionist phase is therefore a learning period
that would allow the least developed countries to acquire general and
technical know-how in the fields of industrial production in order to
become competitive on international markets.
Protection against dumping
States resorting to protectionism invoke unfair competition or dumping practices:
- Monetary dumping: a currency undergoes a devaluation when monetary authorities decide to intervene in the foreign exchange market to lower the value of the currency against other currencies. This makes local products more competitive and imported products more expensive (Marshall Lerner Condition), increasing exports and decreasing imports, and thus improving the trade balance. Countries with a weak currency cause trade imbalances: they have large external surpluses while their competitors have large deficits.
- Tax dumping: some tax haven states have lower corporate and personal tax rates.
- Social dumping: when a state reduces social contributions or maintains very low social standards (for example, in China, labour regulations are less restrictive for employers than elsewhere).
- Environmental dumping: when environmental regulations are less stringent than elsewhere.
Free trade and poverty
Sub-Saharan African countries have a lower income per capita in 2003 than 40 years earlier (Ndulu, World Bank, 2007, p. 33).[47]
Per capita income increased by 37% between 1960 and 1980 and fell by 9%
between 1980 and 2000. Africa's manufacturing sector's share of GDP
decreased from 12% in 1980 to 11% in 2013. In the 1970s, Africa
accounted for more than 3% of world manufacturing output, and now
accounts for 1.5%. Ha-Joon Chang claims that these downturns are the result of free trade policies, and attributes successes in some African countries such as Ethiopia and Rwanda to their abandonment of free trade and adoption of a "developmental state model".
The poor countries that have succeeded in achieving strong and sustainable growth are those that have become mercantilists, not free traders: China, South Korea, Japan, Taiwan.
Thus, whereas in the 1990s, China and India had the same GDP per
capita, China followed a much more mercantilist policy and now has a GDP
per capita three times higher than India's.
Indeed, a significant part of China's rise on the international trade
scene does not come from the supposed benefits of international
competition but from the relocations practiced by companies from
developed countries. Dani Rodrik
points out that it is the countries that have systematically violated
the rules of globalisation that have experienced the strongest growth.
For developed countries that have implemented free trade, the work of E.F. Denison
on growth factors in the United States and Western Europe between 1950
and 1962 shows that the positive effects on growth of trade
liberalization have been negligible in the United States, while in
Western Europe it contributed to a weighted average of only 2% of total
economic growth.
The 'dumping' policies of some countries have also largely
affected developing countries. Studies on the effects of free trade show
that the gains induced by WTO rules for developing countries are very
small.
This has reduced the gain for these countries from an estimated $539
billion in the 2003 LINKAGE model to $22 billion in the 2005 GTAP model.
The 2005 LINKAGE version also reduced gains to 90 billion. As for the "Doha Round", it would have brought in only $4 billion to developing countries (including China...) according to the GTAP model.
However, the models used are actually designed to maximize the positive
effects of trade liberalization. They are characterized by the absence
of taking into account the loss of income caused by the end of tariff
barriers.
Criticism of the theory of comparative advantage
Free trade is based on the theory of comparative advantage.
The classical and neoclassical formulations of comparative advantage
theory differ in the tools they use but share the same basis and logic.
Comparative advantage theory says that market forces lead all factors of
production to their best use in the economy. It indicates that
international free trade would be beneficial for all participating
countries as well as for the world as a whole because they could
increase their overall production and consume more by specializing
according to their comparative advantages. Goods would become cheaper
and available in larger quantities. Moreover, this specialization would
not be the result of chance or political intent, but would be
automatic. However according to some commentators, the theory is based
on assumptions that are neither theoretically nor empirically valid.
International mobility of capital and labour
The
international immobility of labour and capital is essential to the
theory of comparative advantage. Without this, there would be no reason
for international free trade to be regulated by comparative advantages.
Classical and neoclassical economists all assume that labour and capital
do not circulate between nations. At the international level, only the
goods produced can move freely, with capital and labour trapped in
countries. David Ricardo was aware that the international immobility of
labour and capital is an indispensable hypothesis. He devoted half of
his explanation of the theory to it in his book. He even explained that
if labour and capital could move internationally, then comparative
advantages could not determine international trade. Ricardo assumed that
the reasons for the immobility of the capital would be:
the fancied or real insecurity of capital, when not under the immediate control of its owner, together with the natural disinclination which every man has to quit the country of his birth and connexions, and intrust himself with all his habits fixed, to a strange government and new laws
Neoclassical economists, for their part, argue that the scale of
these movements of workers and capital is negligible. They developed the
theory of price compensation by factor that makes these movements
superfluous.
In practice, however, workers move in large numbers from one country to
another. Today, labour migration is truly a global phenomenon. And, with
the reduction in transport and communication costs, capital has become
increasingly mobile and frequently moves from one country to another.
Moreover, the neoclassical assumption that factors are trapped at the
national level has no theoretical basis and the assumption of factor
price equalisation cannot justify international immobility. Moreover,
there is no evidence that factor prices are equal worldwide. Comparative
advantages cannot therefore determine the structure of international
trade.
If they are internationally mobile and the most productive use of
factors is in another country, then free trade will lead them to
migrate to that country. This will benefit the nation to which they
emigrate, but not necessarily the others.
Externalities
An
externality is the term used when the price of a product does not
reflect its cost or real economic value. The classic negative
externality is environmental degradation, which reduces the value of
natural resources without increasing the price of the product that has
caused them harm. The classic positive externality is technological
encroachment, where one company's invention of a product allows others
to copy or build on it, generating wealth that the original company
cannot capture. If prices are wrong due to positive or negative
externalities, free trade will produce sub-optimal results.
For example, goods from a country with lax pollution standards
will be too cheap. As a result, its trading partners will import too
much. And the exporting country will export too much, concentrating its
economy too much in industries that are not as profitable as they seem,
ignoring the damage caused by pollution.
On the positive externalities, if an industry generates
technological spinoffs for the rest of the economy, then free trade can
let that industry be destroyed by foreign competition because the
economy ignores its hidden value. Some industries generate new
technologies, allow improvements in other industries and stimulate
technological advances throughout the economy; losing these industries
means losing all industries that would have resulted in the future.
Cross-industrial movement of productive resources
Comparative
advantage theory deals with the best use of resources and how to put
the economy to its best use. But this implies that the resources used to
manufacture one product can be used to produce another object. If they
cannot, imports will not push the economy into industries better suited
to its comparative advantage and will only destroy existing industries.
For example, when workers cannot move from one industry to
another—usually because they do not have the right skills or do not live
in the right place—changes in the economy's comparative advantage will
not shift them to a more appropriate industry, but rather to
unemployment or precarious and unproductive jobs.
Static vs. dynamic gains via international trade
Comparative
advantage theory allows for a "static" and not a "dynamic" analysis of
the economy. That is, it examines the facts at a single point in time
and determines the best response to those facts at that point in time,
given our productivity in various industries. But when it comes to
long-term growth, it says nothing about how the facts can change
tomorrow and how they can be changed in someone's favour. It does not
indicate how best to transform factors of production into more
productive factors in the future.
According to theory, the only advantage of international trade is
that goods become cheaper and available in larger quantities. Improving
the static efficiency of existing resources would therefore be the only
advantage of international trade. And the neoclassical formulation
assumes that the factors of production are given only exogenously.
Exogenous changes can come from population growth, industrial policies,
the rate of capital accumulation (propensity for security) and
technological inventions, among others. Dynamic developments endogenous
to trade such as economic growth are not integrated into Ricardo's
theory. And this is not affected by what is called "dynamic comparative
advantage". In these models, comparative advantages develop and change
over time, but this change is not the result of trade itself, but of a
change in exogenous factors.
However, the world, and in particular the industrialized
countries, are characterized by dynamic gains endogenous to trade, such
as technological growth that has led to an increase in the standard of
living and wealth of the industrialized world. In addition, dynamic
gains are more important than static gains.
Balanced trade and adjustment mechanisms
A
crucial assumption in both the classical and neoclassical formulation
of comparative advantage theory is that trade is balanced, which means
that the value of imports is equal to the value of each country's
exports. The volume of trade may change, but international trade will
always be balanced at least after a certain adjustment period. The
balance of trade is essential for theory because the resulting
adjustment mechanism is responsible for transforming the comparative
advantages of production costs into absolute price advantages. And this
is necessary because it is the absolute price differences that determine
the international flow of goods. Since consumers buy a good from the
one who sells it cheapest, comparative advantages in terms of production
costs must be transformed into absolute price advantages. In the case
of floating exchange rates, it is the exchange rate adjustment mechanism
that is responsible for this transformation of comparative advantages
into absolute price advantages. In the case of fixed exchange rates,
neoclassical theory suggests that trade is balanced by changes in wage
rates.
So if trade were not balanced in itself and if there were no
adjustment mechanism, there would be no reason to achieve a comparative
advantage. However, trade imbalances are the norm and balanced trade is
in practice only an exception. In addition, financial crises such as the
Asian crisis of the 1990s show that balance of payments imbalances are
rarely benign and do not self-regulate. There is no adjustment mechanism
in practice. Comparative advantages do not turn into price differences
and therefore cannot explain international trade flows.
Thus, theory can very easily recommend a trade policy that gives
us the highest possible standard of living in the short term but none in
the long term. This is what happens when a nation runs a trade deficit,
which necessarily means that it goes into debt with foreigners or sells
its existing assets to them. Thus, the nation applies a frenzy of
consumption in the short term followed by a long-term decline.
International trade as bartering
The
assumption that trade will always be balanced is a corollary of the
fact that trade is understood as barter. The definition of international
trade as barter trade is the basis for the assumption of balanced
trade. Ricardo insists that international trade takes place as if it
were purely a barter trade, a presumption that is maintained by
subsequent classical and neoclassical economists. The quantity of money
theory, which Ricardo uses, assumes that money is neutral and neglects
the velocity of a currency. Money has only one function in
international trade, namely as a means of exchange to facilitate trade.
In practice, however, the velocity of circulation is not
constant and the quantity of money is not neutral for the real economy. A
capitalist world is not characterized by a barter economy but by a
market economy. The main difference in the context of international
trade is that sales and purchases no longer necessarily have to
coincide. The seller is not necessarily obliged to buy immediately.
Thus, money is not only a means of exchange. It is above all a means of
payment and is also used to store value, settle debts and transfer
wealth. Thus, unlike the barter hypothesis of the comparative advantage
theory, money is not a commodity like any other. Rather, it is of
practical importance to specifically own money rather than any
commodity. And money as a store of value in a world of uncertainty has a
significant influence on the motives and decisions of wealth holders
and producers.
Using labour and capital to their full potential
Ricardo
and later classical economists assume that labour tends towards full
employment and that capital is always fully used in a liberalized
economy, because no capital owner will leave its capital unused but will
always seek to make a profit from it. That there is no limit to the use
of capital is a consequence of Jean-Baptiste Say's law, which presumes
that production is limited only by resources and is also adopted by
neoclassical economists.
From a theoretical point of view, comparative advantage theory
must assume that labour or capital is used to its full potential and
that resources limit production. There are two reasons for this: the
realization of gains through international trade and the adjustment
mechanism. In addition, this assumption is necessary for the concept of
opportunity costs. If unemployment (or underutilized resources) exists,
there are no opportunity costs, because the production of one good can
be increased without reducing the production of another good. Since
comparative advantages are determined by opportunity costs in the
neoclassical formulation, these cannot be calculated and this
formulation would lose its logical basis.
If a country's resources were not fully utilized, production and
consumption could be increased at the national level without
participating in international trade. The whole raison d'être of
international trade would disappear, as would the possible gains. In
this case, a State could even earn more by refraining from participating
in international trade and stimulating domestic production, as this
would allow it to employ more labour and capital and increase national
income. Moreover, any adjustment mechanism underlying the theory no
longer works if unemployment exists.
In practice, however, the world is characterised by unemployment.
Unemployment and underemployment of capital and labour are not a
short-term phenomenon, but it is common and widespread. Unemployment and
untapped resources are more the rule than the exception.