A tax (from the Latin taxo) is a compulsory financial charge or some other type of levy imposed upon a taxpayer (an individual or legal entity) by a governmental organization in order to fund various public expenditures. A failure to pay, along with evasion of or resistance to taxation, is punishable by law. Taxes consist of direct or indirect taxes and may be paid in money or as its labour equivalent. The first known taxation took place in Ancient Egypt around 3000–2800 BC.
Most countries have a tax system in place to pay for public, common or agreed national needs and government functions. Some levy a flat percentage rate of taxation on personal annual income, but most scale taxes based on annual income amounts. Most countries charge a tax on individuals income as well as on corporate income. Countries or subunits often also impose wealth taxes, inheritance taxes, estate taxes, gift taxes, property taxes, sales taxes, payroll taxes or tariffs.
In economic terms, taxation transfers wealth from households or businesses to the government. This has effects which can both increase and reduce economic growth and economic welfare. Consequently, taxation is a highly debated topic.
Most countries have a tax system in place to pay for public, common or agreed national needs and government functions. Some levy a flat percentage rate of taxation on personal annual income, but most scale taxes based on annual income amounts. Most countries charge a tax on individuals income as well as on corporate income. Countries or subunits often also impose wealth taxes, inheritance taxes, estate taxes, gift taxes, property taxes, sales taxes, payroll taxes or tariffs.
In economic terms, taxation transfers wealth from households or businesses to the government. This has effects which can both increase and reduce economic growth and economic welfare. Consequently, taxation is a highly debated topic.
Overview
The legal definition, and the economic definition of taxes differ in
some ways such as economists do not regard many transfers to governments
as taxes. For example, some transfers to the public sector are
comparable to prices. Examples include, tuition at public universities,
and fees for utilities provided by local governments. Governments also
obtain resources by "creating" money and coins (for example, by printing
bills and by minting coins), through voluntary gifts (for example,
contributions to public universities and museums), by imposing penalties
(such as traffic fines), by borrowing, and also by confiscating wealth.
From the view of economists, a tax is a non-penal, yet compulsory
transfer of resources from the private to the public sector, levied on a basis of predetermined criteria and without reference to specific benefit received.
In modern taxation systems, governments levy taxes in money; but in-kind and corvée taxation are characteristic of traditional or pre-capitalist
states and their functional equivalents. The method of taxation and the
government expenditure of taxes raised is often highly debated in politics and economics. Tax collection is performed by a government agency such as the Ghana Revenue Authority, Canada Revenue Agency, the Internal Revenue Service (IRS) in the United States, Her Majesty's Revenue and Customs (HMRC) in the United Kingdom or Federal Tax Service in Russia. When taxes are not fully paid, the state may impose civil penalties (such as fines or forfeiture) or criminal penalties (such as incarceration) on the non-paying entity or individual.
Purposes and effects
The levying of taxes aims to raise revenue to fund governing
or to alter prices in order to affect demand. States and their
functional equivalents throughout history have used money provided by
taxation to carry out many functions. Some of these include expenditures
on economic infrastructure (roads, public transportation, sanitation, legal systems, public safety, education, health-care systems), military, scientific research, culture and the arts, public works,
distribution, data collection and dissemination, public insurance, and
the operation of government itself. A government's ability to raise
taxes is called its fiscal capacity.
When expenditures exceed tax revenue, a government accumulates
debt. A portion of taxes may be used to service past debts. Governments
also use taxes to fund welfare and public services. These services can include education systems, pensions for the elderly, unemployment benefits, and public transportation. Energy, water and waste management systems are also common public utilities.
According to the proponents of the chartalist theory of money creation, taxes are not needed for government revenue, as long as the government in question is able to issue fiat money.
According to this view, the purpose of taxation is to maintain the
stability of the currency, express public policy regarding the
distribution of wealth, subsidizing certain industries or population
groups or isolating the costs of certain benefits, such as highways or
social security.
Effects can be divided in two fundamental categories:
- Taxes cause an income effect because they reduce purchasing power to taxpayers.
- Taxes cause a substitution effect when taxation causes a substitution between taxed goods and untaxed goods.
If we consider, for instance, two normal goods, x and y, whose prices are respectively px and py and an individual budget constraint given by the equation xpx + ypy = Y, where Y is the income, the slope of the budget constraint, in a graph where is represented good x on the vertical axis and good y on the horizontal axes, is equal to -py/px . The initial equilibrium is in the point (C), in which budget constraint and indifference curve are tangent, introducing an ad valorem tax on the y good (budget constraint: pxx + py(1 + τ)y = Y) , the budget constraint's slope becomes equal to -py(1 + τ)/px. The new equilibrium is now in the tangent point (A) with a lower indifferent curve.
As can be noticed the tax's introduction causes two consequences:
- It changes the consumers' real income (less purchasing power)
- It raises the relative price of y good.
The income effect shows the variation of y good quantity given by the change of real income. The substitution effect shows the variation of y
good determined by relative prices' variation. This kind of taxation
(that causes substitution effect) can be considered distortionary.
Another example can be the Introduction of an income lump-sum tax (xpx + ypy
= Y - T), with a parallel shift downward of the budget constraint, can
be produced a higher revenue with the same loss of consumers' utility
compared with the property tax case, from another point of view, the
same revenue can be produced with a lower utility sacrifice. The lower
utility (with the same revenue) or the lower revenue (with the same
utility) given by a distortionary tax are called excess pressure. The
same result, reached with an income lump-sum tax, can be obtained with
these following types of taxes (all of them cause only a budget
constraint's shift without causing a substitution effect), the budget
constraint's slope remains the same (-px/py):
- A general tax on consumption: (Budget constraint: px(1 + τ)x + py(1 + τ)y = Y)
- A proportional income tax: (Budget constraint: xpx + ypy = Y(1 - t))
When the t and τ rates are chosen respecting this equation (where t
is the rate of income tax and tau is the consumption tax's rate):
the effects of the two taxes are the same.
A tax effectively changes relative prices of products. Therefore, most economists, especially neoclassical economists, argue that taxation creates market distortion
and results in economic inefficiency unless there are (positive or
negative) externalities associated with the activities that are taxed
that need to be internalized to reach an efficient market outcome. They
have therefore sought to identify the kind of tax system that would
minimize this distortion.
Recent scholarship suggests that in the United States of America,
the federal government effectively taxes investments in higher
education more heavily than it subsidizes higher education, thereby
contributing to a shortage of skilled workers and unusually high
differences in pre-tax earnings between highly educated and
less-educated workers.
Taxes can even have effects on labour supply: we can consider a
model in which the consumer chooses the number of hours spent working
and the amount spent on consumption. Let us suppose that only one good
exists and no income is saved.
Consumers have a given number of hours (H) that is divided
between work (L) and free time (F = H - L). The hourly wage is called w and it tells us the free time's opportunity cost,
i.e. the income to which the individual renounces consuming an
additional hour of free time. Consumption and hours of work have a
positive relationship, more hours of work mean more earnings and,
assuming that workers don't save money, more earnings imply an increase
in consumption (Y = C = wL). Free time and consumption can be
considered as two normal goods (workers have to decide between working
one hour more, that would mean consuming more, or having one more hour
of free time) and the budget constraint is negative inclined (Y = w(H - F)). The indifference curve
related to these two goods has a negative slope and free time becomes
more and more important with high levels of consumption. It's because a
high level of consumption means that people are already spending many
hours working, so, in this situation, they need more free time than
consume and it implies that they have to be paid with a higher salary
to work an additional hour. A proportional income tax, changing budget
constraint's slope (now Y = w(1 - t)(H - F)), implies both
substitution and income effects. The problem now is that the two
effects go in opposite ways: income effect tells us that, with an income
tax, the consumer feels poorer and for this reason he wants to work
more, causing an increase in labour offer. On the other hand,
substitution effect tells us that free time, being a normal good, is now
more convenient compared to consume and it implies a decrease in labour
offer. Therefore, the total effect can be both an increase or a
decrease of labour offer, depending on indifference curve's shape.
The Laffer curve
depicts the amount of government revenue as a function of the rate of
taxation. It shows that for a tax rate above a certain critical rate,
government revenue starts decreasing as the tax rate rises, as a
consequence of a decline in labour supply. This theory supports that, if
the tax rate is above that critical point, a decrease in the tax rate
should imply a rise in labour supply that in turn would lead to an
increase in government revenue.
Governments use different kinds of taxes and vary the tax rates.
They do this in order to distribute the tax burden among individuals or
classes of the population involved in taxable activities, such as the business sector, or to redistribute resources between individuals or classes in the population. Historically, taxes on the poor supported the nobility; modern social-security
systems aim to support the poor, the disabled, or the retired by taxes
on those who are still working. In addition, taxes are applied to fund
foreign aid and military ventures, to influence the macroeconomic performance of the economy (a government's strategy for doing this is called its fiscal policy; see also tax exemption),
or to modify patterns of consumption or employment within an economy,
by making some classes of transaction more or less attractive.
A state's tax system often
reflects its communal values and the values of those in current
political power. To create a system of taxation, a state must make
choices regarding the distribution of the tax burden—who will pay taxes
and how much they will pay—and how the taxes collected will be spent. In
democratic nations where the public elects those in charge of
establishing or administering the tax system, these choices reflect the
type of community that the public wishes to create. In countries where
the public does not have a significant amount of influence over the
system of taxation, that system may reflect more closely the values of
those in power.
All large businesses
incur administrative costs in the process of delivering revenue
collected from customers to the suppliers of the goods or services being
purchased. Taxation is no different; the resource collected from the
public through taxation is always greater than the amount which can be
used by the government. The difference is called the compliance cost
and includes (for example) the labour cost and other expenses incurred
in complying with tax laws and rules. The collection of a tax in order
to spend it on a specified purpose, for example collecting a tax on
alcohol to pay directly for alcoholism-rehabilitation centres, is called
hypothecation. Finance ministers
often dislike this practice, since it reduces their freedom of action.
Some economic theorists regard hypothecation as intellectually dishonest
since, in reality, money is fungible.
Furthermore, it often happens that taxes or excises initially levied to
fund some specific government programs are then later diverted to the
government general fund. In some cases, such taxes are collected in
fundamentally inefficient ways, for example, though highway tolls.
Since governments also resolve commercial disputes, especially in countries with common law, similar arguments are sometimes used to justify a sales tax or value added tax. Some (libertarians, for example) portray most or all forms of taxes as immoral due to their involuntary (and therefore eventually coercive or violent) nature. The most extreme anti-tax view, anarcho-capitalism, holds that all social services should be voluntarily bought by the people using them.
Types of taxes
The Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
(OECD) publishes an analysis of the tax systems of member countries. As
part of such analysis, OECD has developed a definition and system of
classification of internal taxes, generally followed below. In addition, many countries impose taxes (tariffs) on the import of goods.
Income
Income tax
Many jurisdictions tax the income of individuals and business entities, including corporations.
Generally, the authorities impose tax on net profits from a business,
on net gains, and on other income. Computation of income subject to tax
may be determined under accounting principles used in the jurisdiction,
which may be modified or replaced by tax-law principles in the jurisdiction. The incidence of taxation varies by system, and some systems may be viewed as progressive or regressive.
Rates of tax may vary or be constant (flat) by income level. Many
systems allow individuals certain personal allowances and other
non-business reductions to taxable income, although business deductions
tend to be favored over personal deductions.
Personal income tax is often collected on a pay-as-you-earn basis, with small corrections made soon after the end of the tax year.
These corrections take one of two forms: payments to the government,
for taxpayers who have not paid enough during the tax year; and tax refunds
from the government to those who have overpaid. Income-tax systems will
often have deductions available that reduces the total tax liability by
reducing total taxable income. They may allow losses from one type of
income to count against another. For example, a loss on the stock market
may be deducted against taxes paid on wages. Other tax systems may
isolate the loss, such that business losses can only be deducted against
business tax by carrying forward the loss to later tax years.
Negative income
In economics, a negative income tax (abbreviated NIT) is a progressive income tax
system where people earning below a certain amount receive supplemental
payment from the government instead of paying taxes to the government.
Capital gains
Most jurisdictions imposing an income tax treat capital gains
as part of income subject to tax. Capital gain is generally a gain on
sale of capital assets—that is, those assets not held for sale in the
ordinary course of business. Capital assets include personal assets in
many jurisdictions. Some jurisdictions provide preferential rates of tax
or only partial taxation for capital gains. Some jurisdictions impose
different rates or levels of capital-gains taxation based on the length
of time the asset was held. Because tax rates are often much lower for
capital gains than for ordinary income, there is widespread controversy
and dispute about the proper definition of capital.
Corporate
Corporate tax refers to income tax, capital tax, net-worth tax or
other taxes imposed on corporations. Rates of tax and the taxable base
for corporations may differ from those for individuals or for other
taxable persons.
Social-security contributions
Many countries provide publicly funded retirement or health-care systems. In connection with these systems, the country typically requires employers and/or employees to make compulsory payments.
These payments are often computed by reference to wages or earnings
from self-employment. Tax rates are generally fixed, but a different
rate may be imposed on employers than on employees.
Some systems provide an upper limit on earnings subject to the tax. A
few systems provide that the tax is payable only on wages above a
particular amount. Such upper or lower limits may apply for retirement
but not for health-care components of the tax. Some
have argued that such taxes on wages are a form of "forced savings" and
not really a tax, while others point to redistribution through such
systems between generations (from newer cohorts to older cohorts) and
across income levels (from higher income-levels to lower income-levels)
which suggests that such programs are really tax and spending programs.
Payroll or workforce
Unemployment
and similar taxes are often imposed on employers based on total
payroll. These taxes may be imposed in both the country and sub-country
levels.
Wealth
A wealth tax
is a levy on the total value of personal assets, including: bank
deposits, real estate, assets in insurance and pension plans, ownership
of unincorporated businesses, financial securities, and personal trusts. Typically liabilities (primarily mortgages and other loans) are deducted, hence it is sometimes called a net wealth tax.
Property
Recurrent
property taxes may be imposed on immovable property (real property) and
on some classes of movable property. In addition, recurrent taxes may
be imposed on the net wealth of individuals or corporations. Many jurisdictions impose estate tax, gift tax or other inheritance taxes on property at death or at the time of gift transfer. Some jurisdictions impose taxes on financial or capital transactions.
Property taxes
A property tax (or millage tax) is an ad valorem tax
levy on the value of property that the owner of the property is
required to pay to a government in which the property is situated.
Multiple jurisdictions may tax the same property. There are three
general varieties of property: land, improvements to land (immovable
man-made things, e.g. buildings) and personal property (movable things).
Real estate or realty is the combination of land and improvements to land.
Property taxes are usually charged on a recurrent basis (e.g.,
yearly). A common type of property tax is an annual charge on the
ownership of real estate,
where the tax base is the estimated value of the property. For a period
of over 150 years from 1695 the government of England levied a window tax, with the result that one can still see listed buildings
with windows bricked up in order to save their owners money. A similar
tax on hearths existed in France and elsewhere, with similar results.
The two most common types of event-driven property taxes are stamp duty, charged upon change of ownership, and inheritance tax, which many countries impose on the estates of the deceased.
In contrast with a tax on real estate (land and buildings), a land-value tax
(or LVT) is levied only on the unimproved value of the land ("land" in
this instance may mean either the economic term, i.e., all natural
resources, or the natural resources associated with specific areas of
the Earth's surface: "lots" or "land parcels"). Proponents of land-value
tax argue that it is economically justified, as it will not deter
production, distort market mechanisms or otherwise create deadweight losses the way other taxes do.
When real estate is held by a higher government unit or some
other entity not subject to taxation by the local government, the taxing
authority may receive a payment in lieu of taxes to compensate it for some or all of the foregone tax revenues.
In many jurisdictions (including many American states), there is a general tax levied periodically on residents who own personal property
(personalty) within the jurisdiction. Vehicle and boat registration
fees are subsets of this kind of tax. The tax is often designed with
blanket coverage and large exceptions for things like food and clothing.
Household goods are often exempt when kept or used within the
household. Any otherwise non-exempt object can lose its exemption if regularly kept outside the household.
Thus, tax collectors often monitor newspaper articles for stories about
wealthy people who have lent art to museums for public display, because
the artworks have then become subject to personal property tax. If an artwork had to be sent to another state for some touch-ups, it may have become subject to personal property tax in that state as well.
Inheritance
Inheritance tax, estate tax, and death tax or duty are the names
given to various taxes which arise on the death of an individual. In
United States tax law,
there is a distinction between an estate tax and an inheritance tax:
the former taxes the personal representatives of the deceased, while the
latter taxes the beneficiaries of the estate. However, this distinction
does not apply in other jurisdictions; for example, if using this
terminology UK inheritance tax would be an estate tax.
Expatriation
An expatriation tax is a tax on individuals who renounce their citizenship or residence. The tax is often imposed based on a deemed disposition of all the individual's property. One example is the United States under the American Jobs Creation Act,
where any individual who has a net worth of $2 million or an average
income-tax liability of $127,000 who renounces his or her citizenship
and leaves the country is automatically assumed to have done so for tax
avoidance reasons and is subject to a higher tax rate.
Transfer
Historically, in many countries, a contract needs to have a stamp
affixed to make it valid. The charge for the stamp is either a fixed
amount or a percentage of the value of the transaction. In most
countries, the stamp has been abolished but stamp duty
remains. Stamp duty is levied in the UK on the purchase of shares and
securities, the issue of bearer instruments, and certain partnership
transactions. Its modern derivatives, stamp duty reserve tax and stamp duty land tax,
are respectively charged on transactions involving securities and land.
Stamp duty has the effect of discouraging speculative purchases of
assets by decreasing liquidity. In the United States,
transfer tax is often charged by the state or local government and (in
the case of real property transfers) can be tied to the recording of the
deed or other transfer documents.
Wealth (net worth)
Some countries' governments will require declaration of the tax payers' balance sheet (assets and liabilities), and from that exact a tax on net worth
(assets minus liabilities), as a percentage of the net worth, or a
percentage of the net worth exceeding a certain level. The tax may be
levied on "natural" or "legal persons."
Goods and services
Value added
A value added tax (VAT), also known as Goods and Services Tax
(G.S.T), Single Business Tax, or Turnover Tax in some countries, applies
the equivalent of a sales tax to every operation that creates value. To
give an example, sheet steel is imported by a machine manufacturer.
That manufacturer will pay the VAT on the purchase price, remitting that
amount to the government. The manufacturer will then transform the
steel into a machine, selling the machine for a higher price to a
wholesale distributor. The manufacturer will collect the VAT on the
higher price, but will remit to the government only the excess related
to the "value added" (the price over the cost of the sheet steel). The
wholesale distributor will then continue the process, charging the
retail distributor the VAT on the entire price to the retailer, but
remitting only the amount related to the distribution mark-up to the
government. The last VAT amount is paid by the eventual retail customer
who cannot recover any of the previously paid VAT. For a VAT and sales
tax of identical rates, the total tax paid is the same, but it is paid
at differing points in the process.
VAT is usually administrated by requiring the company to complete
a VAT return, giving details of VAT it has been charged (referred to as
input tax) and VAT it has charged to others (referred to as output
tax). The difference between output tax and input tax is payable to the
Local Tax Authority.
Many tax authorities have introduced automated VAT which has increased accountability and auditability, by utilizing computer-systems, thereby also enabling anti-cybercrime offices as well.
Sales
Sales taxes are levied when a commodity is sold to its final
consumer. Retail organizations contend that such taxes discourage retail
sales. The question of whether they are generally progressive or
regressive is a subject of much current debate. People with higher
incomes spend a lower proportion of them, so a flat-rate sales tax will
tend to be regressive. It is therefore common to exempt food, utilities
and other necessities from sales taxes, since poor people spend a higher
proportion of their incomes on these commodities, so such exemptions
make the tax more progressive. This is the classic "You pay for what you
spend" tax, as only those who spend money on non-exempt (i.e. luxury)
items pay the tax.
A small number of U.S. states rely entirely on sales taxes for
state revenue, as those states do not levy a state income tax. Such
states tend to have a moderate to large amount of tourism or inter-state
travel that occurs within their borders, allowing the state to benefit
from taxes from people the state would otherwise not tax. In this way,
the state is able to reduce the tax burden on its citizens. The U.S.
states that do not levy a state income tax are Alaska, Tennessee,
Florida, Nevada, South Dakota, Texas, Washington state, and Wyoming. Additionally, New Hampshire and Tennessee levy state income taxes only on dividends
and interest income. Of the above states, only Alaska and New Hampshire
do not levy a state sales tax. Additional information can be obtained
at the Federation of Tax Administrators website.
In the United States, there is a growing movement
for the replacement of all federal payroll and income taxes (both
corporate and personal) with a national retail sales tax and monthly tax
rebate to households of citizens and legal resident aliens. The tax
proposal is named FairTax.
In Canada, the federal sales tax is called the Goods and Services tax
(GST) and now stands at 5%. The provinces of British Columbia,
Saskatchewan, Manitoba, and Prince Edward Island also have a provincial
sales tax [PST]. The provinces of Nova Scotia, New Brunswick,
Newfoundland & Labrador, and Ontario have harmonized their
provincial sales taxes with the GST—Harmonized Sales Tax [HST], and thus
is a full VAT. The province of Quebec collects the Quebec Sales Tax
[QST] which is based on the GST with certain differences. Most
businesses can claim back the GST, HST and QST they pay, and so
effectively it is the final consumer who pays the tax.
Excises
An excise duty is an indirect tax
imposed upon goods during the process of their manufacture, production
or distribution, and is usually proportionate to their quantity or
value. Excise duties were first introduced into England in the year
1643, as part of a scheme of revenue and taxation devised by
parliamentarian John Pym and approved by the Long Parliament.
These duties consisted of charges on beer, ale, cider, cherry wine and
tobacco, to which list were afterwards added paper, soap, candles, malt,
hops, and sweets. The basic principle of excise duties was that they
were taxes on the production, manufacture or distribution of articles
which could not be taxed through the customs house,
and revenue derived from that source is called excise revenue proper.
The fundamental conception of the term is that of a tax on articles
produced or manufactured in a country. In the taxation of such articles
of luxury as spirits, beer, tobacco, and cigars, it has been the
practice to place a certain duty on the importation of these articles (a
customs duty).
Excises (or exemptions from them) are also used to modify consumption patterns of a certain area (social engineering). For example, a high excise is used to discourage alcohol consumption, relative to other goods. This may be combined with hypothecation if the proceeds are then used to pay for the costs of treating illness caused by alcohol abuse. Similar taxes may exist on tobacco, pornography, etc., and they may be collectively referred to as "sin taxes". A carbon tax
is a tax on the consumption of carbon-based non-renewable fuels, such
as petrol, diesel-fuel, jet fuels, and natural gas. The object is to
reduce the release of carbon into the atmosphere. In the United Kingdom,
vehicle excise duty is an annual tax on vehicle ownership.
Tariff
An import or export tariff (also called customs duty or impost) is a
charge for the movement of goods through a political border. Tariffs
discourage trade,
and they may be used by governments to protect domestic industries. A
proportion of tariff revenues is often hypothecated to pay government to
maintain a navy or border police. The classic ways of cheating a tariff
are smuggling
or declaring a false value of goods. Tax, tariff and trade rules in
modern times are usually set together because of their common impact on industrial policy, investment policy, and agricultural policy. A trade bloc
is a group of allied countries agreeing to minimize or eliminate
tariffs against trade with each other, and possibly to impose protective
tariffs on imports from outside the bloc. A customs union has a common external tariff, and the participating countries share the revenues from tariffs on goods entering the customs union.
In some societies, tariffs also could be imposed by local
authorities on the movement of goods between regions (or via specific
internal gateways). A notable example is the likin, which became an important revenue source for local governments in the late Qing China.
Other
License fees
Occupational
taxes or license fees may be imposed on businesses or individuals
engaged in certain businesses. Many jurisdictions impose a tax on
vehicles.
Poll
A poll tax, also called a per capita tax, or capitation tax, is a tax that levies a set amount per individual. It is an example of the concept of fixed tax. One of the earliest taxes mentioned in the Bible
of a half-shekel per annum from each adult Jew (Ex. 30:11–16) was a
form of poll tax. Poll taxes are administratively cheap because they are
easy to compute and collect and difficult to cheat. Economists have
considered poll taxes economically efficient because people are presumed
to be in fixed supply and poll taxes therefore do not lead to economic
distortions. However, poll taxes are very unpopular because poorer
people pay a higher proportion of their income than richer people. In
addition, the supply of people is in fact not fixed over time: on
average, couples will choose to have fewer children if a poll tax is
imposed. The introduction of a poll tax in medieval England was the primary cause of the 1381 Peasants' Revolt.
Scotland was the first to be used to test the new poll tax in 1989 with
England and Wales in 1990. The change from a progressive local taxation
based on property values to a single-rate form of taxation regardless
of ability to pay (the Community Charge,
but more popularly referred to as the Poll Tax), led to widespread
refusal to pay and to incidents of civil unrest, known colloquially as
the 'Poll Tax Riots'.
Other
Some types of taxes have been proposed but not actually adopted in any major jurisdiction. These include:
- Bank tax
- Financial transaction taxes including currency transaction taxes
Descriptive labels
Ad valorem and per unit
An ad valorem tax is one where the tax base is the value of a
good, service, or property. Sales taxes, tariffs, property taxes,
inheritance taxes, and value added taxes are different types of ad
valorem tax. An ad valorem tax is typically imposed at the time of a
transaction (sales tax or value added tax (VAT)) but it may be imposed
on an annual basis (property tax) or in connection with another
significant event (inheritance tax or tariffs).
In contrast to ad valorem taxation is a per unit tax, where the tax base is the quantity of something, regardless of its price. An excise tax is an example.
Consumption
Consumption tax refers to any tax on non-investment spending, and can
be implemented by means of a sales tax, consumer value added tax, or by
modifying an income tax to allow for unlimited deductions for
investment or savings.
Environmental
This includes natural resources consumption tax, greenhouse gas tax (Carbon tax), "sulfuric tax", and others. The stated purpose is to reduce the environmental impact by repricing. Economists describe environmental impacts as negative externalities. As early as 1920, Arthur Pigou suggested a tax to deal with externalities (see also the section on Increased economic welfare below). The proper implementation of environmental taxes has been the subject of a long lasting debate.
Proportional, progressive, regressive, and lump-sum
An
important feature of tax systems is the percentage of the tax burden as
it relates to income or consumption. The terms progressive, regressive,
and proportional are used to describe the way the rate progresses from
low to high, from high to low, or proportionally. The terms describe a
distribution effect, which can be applied to any type of tax system
(income or consumption) that meets the definition.
- A progressive tax is a tax imposed so that the effective tax rate increases as the amount to which the rate is applied increases.
- The opposite of a progressive tax is a regressive tax, where the effective tax rate decreases as the amount to which the rate is applied increases. This effect is commonly produced where means testing is used to withdraw tax allowances or state benefits.
- In between is a proportional tax, where the effective tax rate is fixed, while the amount to which the rate is applied increases.
- A lump-sum tax is a tax that is a fixed amount, no matter the change in circumstance of the taxed entity. This in actuality is a regressive tax as those with lower income must use higher percentage of their income than those with higher income and therefore the effect of the tax reduces as a function of income.
The terms can also be used to apply meaning to the taxation of select
consumption, such as a tax on luxury goods and the exemption of basic
necessities may be described as having progressive effects as it
increases a tax burden on high end consumption and decreases a tax
burden on low end consumption.
Direct and indirect
Taxes are sometimes referred to as "direct taxes" or "indirect
taxes". The meaning of these terms can vary in different contexts, which
can sometimes lead to confusion. An economic definition, by Atkinson,
states that "...direct taxes may be adjusted to the individual
characteristics of the taxpayer, whereas indirect taxes are levied on
transactions irrespective of the circumstances of buyer or seller." According to this definition, for example, income tax is "direct", and sales tax is "indirect".
In law, the terms may have different meanings. In U.S. constitutional law, for instance, direct taxes refer to poll taxes and property taxes, which are based on simple existence or ownership. Indirect taxes are imposed on events, rights, privileges, and activities.
Thus, a tax on the sale of property would be considered an indirect
tax, whereas the tax on simply owning the property itself would be a
direct tax.
Fees and effective
Governments may charge user fees,
tolls, or other types of assessments in exchange of particular goods,
services, or use of property. These are generally not considered taxes,
as long as they are levied as payment for a direct benefit to the
individual paying. Such fees include:
- Tolls: a fee charged to travel via a road, bridge, tunnel, canal, waterway or other transportation facilities. Historically tolls have been used to pay for public bridge, road and tunnel projects. They have also been used in privately constructed transport links. The toll is likely to be a fixed charge, possibly graduated for vehicle type, or for distance on long routes.
- User fees, such as those charged for use of parks or other government owned facilities.
- Ruling fees charged by governmental agencies to make determinations in particular situations.
Some scholars refer to certain economic effects as taxes, though they are not levies imposed by governments. These include:
- Inflation tax: the economic disadvantage suffered by holders of cash and cash equivalents in one denomination of currency due to the effects of expansionary monetary policy
- Financial repression: Government policies such as interest-rate caps on government debt, financial regulations such as reserve requirements and capital controls, and barriers to entry in markets where the government owns or controls businesses.
History
The first known system of taxation was in Ancient Egypt around 3000–2800 BC in the First Dynasty of Egypt of the Old Kingdom of Egypt. The earliest and most widespread form of taxation was the corvée and tithe. The corvée was forced labour provided to the state by peasants too poor to pay other forms of taxation (labour in ancient Egyptian is a synonym for taxes).
Records from the time document that the Pharaoh would conduct a
biennial tour of the kingdom, collecting tithes from the people. Other
records are granary receipts on limestone flakes and papyrus. Early taxation is also described in the Bible. In Genesis (chapter 47, verse 24 – the New International Version), it states "But when the crop comes in, give a fifth of it to Pharaoh. The other four-fifths you may keep as seed for the fields and as food for yourselves and your households and your children". Joseph was telling the people of Egypt
how to divide their crop, providing a portion to the Pharaoh. A share
(20%) of the crop was the tax (in this case, a special rather than an
ordinary tax, as it was gathered against an expected famine) The stock
made by was returned and equally shared with the people of Egypt and
traded with the surrounding nations thus saving and elevating Egypt.
In the Persian Empire, a regulated and sustainable tax system was introduced by Darius I the Great in 500 BC; the Persian system of taxation was tailored to each Satrapy
(the area ruled by a Satrap or provincial governor). At differing
times, there were between 20 and 30 Satrapies in the Empire and each was
assessed according to its supposed productivity. It was the
responsibility of the Satrap to collect the due amount and to send it to
the treasury, after deducting his expenses (the expenses and the power
of deciding precisely how and from whom to raise the money in the
province, offer maximum opportunity for rich pickings). The quantities
demanded from the various provinces gave a vivid picture of their
economic potential. For instance, Babylon was assessed for the highest amount and for a startling mixture of commodities; 1,000 silver talents and four months supply of food for the army. India,
a province fabled for its gold, was to supply gold dust equal in value
to the very large amount of 4,680 silver talents. Egypt was known for
the wealth of its crops; it was to be the granary of the Persian Empire
(and, later, of the Roman Empire) and was required to provide 120,000 measures of grain in addition to 700 talents of silver. This tax was exclusively levied on Satrapies based on their lands, productive capacity and tribute levels.
The Rosetta Stone, a tax concession issued by Ptolemy V in 196 BC and written in three languages "led to the most famous decipherment in history—the cracking of hieroglyphics".
Islamic rulers imposed Zakat (a tax on Muslims) and Jizya (a poll tax on conquered non-Muslims). In India this practice began in the 11th century.
Trends
Numerous
records of government tax collection in Europe since at least the 17th
century are still available today. But taxation levels are hard to
compare to the size and flow of the economy since production
numbers are not as readily available. Government expenditures and
revenue in France during the 17th century went from about 24.30 million livres in 1600–10 to about 126.86 million livres in 1650–59 to about 117.99 million livres in 1700–10 when government debt had reached 1.6 billion livres. In 1780–89, it reached 421.50 million livres. Taxation as a percentage of production of final goods may have reached 15–20% during the 17th century in places such as France, the Netherlands, and Scandinavia.
During the war-filled years of the eighteenth and early nineteenth
century, tax rates in Europe increased dramatically as war became more
expensive and governments became more centralized and adept at gathering
taxes. This increase was greatest in England, Peter Mathias
and Patrick O'Brien found that the tax burden increased by 85% over
this period. Another study confirmed this number, finding that per
capita tax revenues had grown almost sixfold over the eighteenth
century, but that steady economic growth had made the real burden on
each individual only double over this period before the industrial
revolution. Effective tax rates were higher in Britain than France the years before the French Revolution,
twice in per capita income comparison, but they were mostly placed on
international trade. In France, taxes were lower but the burden was
mainly on landowners, individuals, and internal trade and thus created
far more resentment.
Taxation as a percentage of GDP 2016 was 45.9% in Denmark, 45.3% in France, 33.2% in the United Kingdom, 26% in the United States, and among all OECD members an average of 34.3%.
Forms
In monetary economies prior to fiat banking, a critical form of taxation was seigniorage, the tax on the creation of money.
Other obsolete forms of taxation include:
- Scutage, which is paid in lieu of military service; strictly speaking, it is a commutation of a non-tax obligation rather than a tax as such but functioning as a tax in practice.
- Tallage, a tax on feudal dependents.
- Tithe, a tax-like payment (one tenth of one's earnings or agricultural produce), paid to the Church (and thus too specific to be a tax in strict technical terms). This should not be confused with the modern practice of the same name which is normally voluntary.
- (Feudal) aids, a type of tax or due that was paid by a vassal to his lord during feudal times.
- Danegeld, a medieval land tax originally raised to pay off raiding Danes and later used to fund military expenditures.
- Carucage, a tax which replaced the danegeld in England.
- Tax farming, the principle of assigning the responsibility for tax revenue collection to private citizens or groups.
- Socage, a feudal tax system based on land rent.
- Burgage, a feudal tax system based on land rent.
Some principalities taxed windows, doors, or cabinets to reduce consumption of imported glass and hardware. Armoires, hutches, and wardrobes
were employed to evade taxes on doors and cabinets. In some
circumstances, taxes are also used to enforce public policy like
congestion charge (to cut road traffic and encourage public transport)
in London. In Tsarist Russia, taxes
were clamped on beards. Today, one of the most-complicated taxation
systems worldwide is in Germany. Three quarters of the world's taxation
literature refers to the German system. Under the German system, there are 118 laws, 185 forms, and 96,000 regulations, spending €3.7 billion to collect the income tax. In the United States, the IRS has about 1,177 forms and instructions, 28.4111 megabytes of Internal Revenue Code which contained 3.8 million words as of 1 February 2010, numerous tax regulations in the Code of Federal Regulations, and supplementary material in the Internal Revenue Bulletin.
Today, governments in more advanced economies (i.e. Europe and North
America) tend to rely more on direct taxes, while developing economies
(i.e. India and several African countries) rely more on indirect taxes.
Economic effects
In economic terms, taxation transfers wealth from households or businesses to the government of a nation. Adam Smith writes in The Wealth of Nations that
- "…the economic incomes of private people are of three main types: rent, profit and wages. Ordinary taxpayers will ultimately pay their taxes from at least one of these revenue sources. The government may intend that a particular tax should fall exclusively on rent, profit, or wages – and that another tax should fall on all three private income sources jointly. However, many taxes will inevitably fall on resources and persons very different from those intended … Good taxes meet four major criteria. They are (1) proportionate to incomes or abilities to pay (2) certain rather than arbitrary (3) payable at times and in ways convenient to the taxpayers and (4) cheap to administer and collect."
The side-effects of taxation (such as economic distortions) and theories about how best to tax are an important subject in microeconomics. Taxation is almost never a simple transfer of wealth. Economic theories of taxation approach the question of how to maximize economic welfare through taxation.
A 2019 study looking at the impact of tax cuts for different
income groups, it was tax cuts for low-income groups that had the
greatest positive impact on employment growth. Tax cuts for the wealthiest top 10% had a small impact.
Incidence
Law establishes from whom a tax is collected. In many countries, taxes are imposed on business (such as corporate taxes or portions of payroll taxes). However, who ultimately pays the tax (the tax "burden") is determined by the marketplace as taxes become embedded
into production costs. Economic theory suggests that the economic
effect of tax does not necessarily fall at the point where it is legally
levied. For instance, a tax on employment paid by employers will impact
on the employee, at least in the long run. The greatest share of the
tax burden tends to fall on the most inelastic factor involved—the part
of the transaction which is affected least by a change in price. So, for
instance, a tax on wages in a town will (at least in the long run)
affect property-owners in that area.
Depending on how quantities supplied and demanded vary with price
(the "elasticities" of supply and demand), a tax can be absorbed by the
seller (in the form of lower pre-tax prices), or by the buyer (in the
form of higher post-tax prices). If the elasticity of supply is low,
more of the tax will be paid by the supplier. If the elasticity of
demand is low, more will be paid by the customer; and, contrariwise for
the cases where those elasticities are high. If the seller is a
competitive firm, the tax burden is distributed over the factors of production
depending on the elasticities thereof; this includes workers (in the
form of lower wages), capital investors (in the form of loss to
shareholders), landowners (in the form of lower rents), entrepreneurs
(in the form of lower wages of superintendence) and customers (in the
form of higher prices).
To show this relationship, suppose that the market price of a
product is $1.00, and that a $0.50 tax is imposed on the product that,
by law, is to be collected from the seller. If the product has an
elastic demand, a greater portion of the tax will be absorbed by the
seller. This is because goods with elastic demand cause a large decline
in quantity demanded for a small increase in price. Therefore, in order
to stabilize sales, the seller absorbs more of the additional tax
burden. For example, the seller might drop the price of the product to
$0.70 so that, after adding in the tax, the buyer pays a total of $1.20,
or $0.20 more than he did before the $0.50 tax was imposed. In this
example, the buyer has paid $0.20 of the $0.50 tax (in the form of a
post-tax price) and the seller has paid the remaining $0.30 (in the form
of a lower pre-tax price).
Increased economic welfare
Government spending
The purpose of taxation is to provide for government spending without inflation. The provision of public goods such as roads and other infrastructure, schools, a social safety net,
health care, national defense, law enforcement, and a courts system
increases the economic welfare of society if the benefit outweighs the
costs involved.
Pigovian
The existence of a tax can increase economic efficiency in some cases. If there is a negative externality
associated with a good, meaning that it has negative effects not felt
by the consumer, then a free market will trade too much of that good. By
taxing the good, the government can increase overall welfare as well as
raising revenue. This type of tax is called a Pigovian tax, after economist Arthur Pigou.
Possible Pigovian taxes include those on polluting fuels (like petrol), taxes on goods which incur public healthcare costs (such as alcohol or tobacco), and charges for existing 'free' public goods (like congestion charging) are another possibility.
Reduced inequality
Progressive taxation may reduce economic inequality. This effect occurs even when the tax revenue isn't redistributed.
Reduced economic welfare
Most taxes (see below) have side effects that reduce economic welfare, either by mandating unproductive labor (compliance costs) or by creating distortions to economic incentives (deadweight loss and perverse incentives).
Cost of compliance
Although
governments must spend money on tax collection activities, some of the
costs, particularly for keeping records and filling out forms, are borne
by businesses and by private individuals. These are collectively called
costs of compliance. More complex tax systems tend to have higher
compliance costs. This fact can be used as the basis for practical or
moral arguments in favor of tax simplification (such as the FairTax or OneTax, and some flat tax proposals).
Deadweight costs
In the absence of negative externalities, the introduction of taxes into a market reduces economic efficiency by causing deadweight loss. In a competitive market the price of a particular economic good
adjusts to ensure that all trades which benefit both the buyer and the
seller of a good occur. The introduction of a tax causes the price
received by the seller to be less than the cost to the buyer by the
amount of the tax. This causes fewer transactions to occur, which
reduces economic welfare; the individuals or businesses involved are less well off than before the tax. The tax burden and the amount of deadweight cost is dependent on the elasticity of supply and demand for the good taxed.
Most taxes—including income tax and sales tax—can
have significant deadweight costs. The only way to avoid deadweight
costs in an economy that is generally competitive is to refrain from
taxes that change economic incentives. Such taxes include the land value tax, where the tax is on a good in completely inelastic supply, a lump sum tax such as a poll tax (head tax) which is paid by all adults regardless of their choices. Arguably a windfall profits tax which is entirely unanticipated can also fall into this category.
Deadweight loss does not account for the effect taxes have in
leveling the business playing field. Businesses that have more money are
better suited to fend off competition. It is common that an industry
with a small amount of very large corporations has a very high barrier
of entry for new entrants coming into the marketplace. This is due to
the fact that the larger the corporation, the better its position to
negotiate with suppliers. Also, larger companies may be able to operate
at low or even negative profits for extended periods of time, thus
pushing out competition. More progressive taxation of profits, however,
would reduce such barriers for new entrants, thereby increasing
competition and ultimately benefiting consumers.
Perverse incentives
Complexity of the tax code in developed economies offer perverse tax incentives. The more details of tax policy there are, the more opportunities for legal tax avoidance and illegal tax evasion.
These not only result in lost revenue, but involve additional costs:
for instance, payments made for tax advice are essentially deadweight
costs because they add no wealth to the economy. Perverse incentives also occur because of non-taxable 'hidden' transactions; for instance, a sale from one company to another might be liable for sales tax, but if the same goods were shipped from one branch of a corporation to another, no tax would be payable.
To address these issues, economists often suggest simple and
transparent tax structures which avoid providing loopholes. Sales tax,
for instance, can be replaced with a value added tax which disregards intermediate transactions.
In developing countries
Following
Nicolas Kaldor's research, public finance in developing countries is
strongly tied to state capacity and financial development. As state
capacity develops, states not only increase the level of taxation but
also the pattern of taxation. With the increase of larger tax bases and
the diminish of the importance of trading tax, while income tax gains
more importance.
According to Tilly's argument, state capacity evolves as response to the
emergence of war. War is an incentive for states to raise tax and
strengthen states capacity. Historically, many taxation breakthroughs
took place during the wartime. The introduction of income tax in Britain
was due to the Napoleonic War in 1798. US first introduce income tax
during Civil War.
Taxation is constrained by the fiscal and legal capacities of a country.
Fiscal and legal capacities also complement each other. A well-designed
tax system can minimize efficiency loss and boost economic growth. With
better compliance and better support to financial institutions and
individual property, the government will be able to collect more tax.
Although wealthier countries have higher tax revenue, economic growth
does not always translate to higher tax revenue. For example, in India,
increases in exemptions leads to the stagnation of income tax revenue at
around 0.5% of GDP since 1986.
Researchers for EPS PEAKS stated that the core purpose of taxation is revenue mobilisation,
providing resources for National Budgets, and forming an important part
of macroeconomic management. They said economic theory
has focused on the need to 'optimise' the system through balancing
efficiency and equity, understanding the impacts on production, and
consumption as well as distribution, redistribution, and welfare.
They state that taxes and tax reliefs have also been used as a tool for behavioural change, to influence investment decisions, labour supply, consumption patterns,
and positive and negative economic spill-overs (externalities), and
ultimately, the promotion of economic growth and development. The tax
system and its administration also play an important role in
state-building and governance, as a principal form of 'social contract'
between the state and citizens who can, as taxpayers, exert
accountability on the state as a consequence.
The researchers wrote that domestic revenue forms an important
part of a developing country's public financing as it is more stable and
predictable than Overseas Development Assistance
and necessary for a country to be self-sufficient. They found that
domestic revenue flows are, on average, already much larger than ODA,
with aid worth less than 10% of collected taxes in Africa as a whole.
However, in a quarter of African countries Overseas Development Assistance does exceed tax collection,
with these more likely to be non-resource-rich countries. This suggests
countries making most progress replacing aid with tax revenue tend to
be those benefiting disproportionately from rising prices of energy and
commodities.
The author found tax revenue as a percentage of GDP varying greatly around a global average of 19%.
This data also indicates countries with higher GDP tend to have higher
tax to GDP ratios, demonstrating that higher income is associated with
more than proportionately higher tax revenue. On average, high-income
countries have tax revenue as a percentage of GDP of around 22%,
compared to 18% in middle-income countries and 14% in low-income
countries.
In high-income countries, the highest tax-to-GDP ratio is in Denmark
at 47% and the lowest is in Kuwait at 0.8%, reflecting low taxes from
strong oil revenues. Long-term average performance of tax revenue as a
share of GDP in low-income countries has been largely stagnant, although
most have shown some improvement in more recent years. On average,
resource-rich countries have made the most progress, rising from 10% in
the mid-1990s to around 17% in 2008. Non resource rich countries made
some progress, with average tax revenues increasing from 10% to 15% over
the same period.
Many low-income countries have a tax-to-GDP ratio of less than
15% which could be due to low tax potential, such as a limited taxable
economic activity, or low tax effort due to policy choice,
non-compliance, or administrative constraints.
Some low-income countries have relatively high tax-to- GDP ratios due to resource tax revenues (e.g. Angola) or relatively efficient tax administration (e.g. Kenya, Brazil) whereas some middle-income countries have lower tax-to-GDP ratios (e.g. Malaysia) which reflect a more tax-friendly policy choice.
While overall tax revenues have remained broadly constant, the
global trend shows trade taxes have been declining as a proportion of
total revenues(IMF, 2011), with the share of revenue shifting away from
border trade taxes towards domestically levied sales taxes
on goods and services. Low-income countries tend to have a higher
dependence on trade taxes, and a smaller proportion of income and
consumption taxes, when compared to high income countries.
One indicator of the taxpaying experience was captured in the 'Doing Business' survey,
which compares the total tax rate, time spent complying with tax
procedures and the number of payments required through the year, across
176 countries. The 'easiest' countries in which to pay taxes are located
in the Middle East with the UAE ranking first, followed by Qatar and Saudi Arabia, most likely reflecting low tax regimes in those countries. Countries in Sub-Saharan Africa are among the 'hardest' to pay with the Central African Republic, Republic of Congo, Guinea and Chad in the bottom 5, reflecting higher total tax rates and a greater administrative burden to comply.
Key facts
The below facts were compiled by EPS PEAKS researchers:
- Trade liberalisation has led to a decline in trade taxes as a share of total revenues and GDP.
- Resource-rich countries tend to collect more revenue as a share of GDP, but this is more volatile. Sub-Saharan African countries that are resource rich have performed better tax collecting than non-resource-rich countries, but revenues are more volatile from year to year. By strengthening revenue management, there are huge opportunities for investment for development and growth.
- Developing countries have an informal sector representing an average of around 40%, perhaps up to 60% in some. Informal sectors feature many small informal traders who may not be efficient in bringing into the tax net, since the cost of collection is high and revenue potential limited (although there are broader governance benefits). There is also an issue of non-compliant companies who are 'hard to tax', evading taxes and should be brought into the tax net.
- In many low-income countries, the majority of revenue is collected from a narrow tax base, sometimes because of a limited range of taxable economic activities. There is therefore dependence on few taxpayers, often multinationals, that can exacerbate the revenue challenge by minimising their tax liability, in some cases abusing a lack of capacity in revenue authorities, sometimes through transfer pricing abuse.
- Developing and developed countries face huge challenges in taxing multinationals and international citizens. Estimates of tax revenue losses from evasion and avoidance in developing countries are limited by a lack of data and methodological shortcomings, but some estimates are significant.
- Countries use incentives to attract investment but doing this may be unnecessarily giving up revenue as evidence suggests that investors are influenced more by economic fundamentals like market size, infrastructure, and skills, and only marginally by tax incentives (IFC investor surveys). For example, even though the Armenian government supports the IT sector and improves the investment climate, the small size of the domestic market, low wages, low demand for productivity enhancement tools, financial constraints, high software piracy rates, and other factors make growth in this sector a slow process. Meaning that tax incentives do not contribute to the development of the sector as much as it is thought to contribute.
- In low-income countries, compliance costs are high, they are lengthy processes, frequent tax payments, bribes and corruption.
- Administrations are often under-resourced, resources aren't effectively targeted on areas of greatest impact, and mid-level management is weak. Coordination between domestic and customs is weak, which is especially important for VAT. Weak administration, governance and corruption tend to be associated with low revenue collections (IMF, 2011).
- Evidence on the effect of aid on tax revenues is inconclusive. Tax revenue is more stable and sustainable than aid. While a disincentive effect of aid on revenue may be expected and was supported by some early studies, recent evidence does not support that conclusion, and in some cases, points towards higher tax revenue following support for revenue mobilisation.
- Of all regions, Africa has the highest total tax rates borne by business at 57.4% of profit on average, but has reduced the most since 2004, from 70%, partly due to introducing VAT and this is likely to have a beneficial effect on attracting investment.
- Fragile states are less able to expand tax revenue as a percentage of GDP and any gains are more difficult to sustain. Tax administration tends to collapse if conflict reduces state controlled territory or reduces productivity. As economies are rebuilt after conflicts, there can be good progress in developing effective tax systems. Liberia expanded from 10.6% of GDP in 2003 to 21.3% in 2011. Mozambique increased from 10.5% of GDP in 1994 to around 17.7% in 2011.
Summary
Aid
interventions in revenue can support revenue mobilisation for growth,
improve tax system design and administrative effectiveness, and
strengthen governance and compliance.
The author of the Economics Topic Guide found that the best aid
modalities for revenue depend on country circumstances, but should aim
to align with government interests and facilitate effective planning and
implementation of activities under an evidence-based tax reform.
Lastly, she found that identifying areas for further reform requires
country-specific diagnostic assessment: broad areas for developing
countries identified internationally (e.g. IMF) include, for example
property taxation for local revenues, strengthening expenditure
management, and effective taxation of extractive industries and
multinationals.
Views
Support
Every tax, however, is, to the person who pays it, a badge, not of slavery, but of liberty. – Adam Smith (1776), Wealth of Nations
According to most political philosophies, taxes are justified as they fund activities that are necessary and beneficial to society. Additionally, progressive taxation can be used to reduce economic inequality in a society. According to this view, taxation in modern nation-states benefit the majority of the population and social development. A common presentation of this view, paraphrasing various statements by Oliver Wendell Holmes, Jr. is "Taxes are the price of civilization".
It can also be argued that in a democracy,
because the government is the party performing the act of imposing
taxes, society as a whole decides how the tax system should be
organized. The American Revolution's "No taxation without representation" slogan implied this view. For traditional conservatives,
the payment of taxation is justified as part of the general obligations
of citizens to obey the law and support established institutions. The
conservative position is encapsulated in perhaps the most famous adage of public finance, "An old tax is a good tax".
Conservatives advocate the "fundamental conservative premise that no
one should be excused from paying for government, lest they come to
believe that government is costless to them with the certain consequence
that they will demand more government 'services'." Social democrats generally favor higher levels of taxation to fund public provision of a wide range of services such as universal health care and education, as well as the provision of a range of welfare benefits. As argued by Tony Crosland and others, the capacity to tax income from capital is a central element of the social democratic case for a mixed economy as against Marxist arguments for comprehensive public ownership of capital. Many libertarians recommend a minimal level of taxation in order to maximize the protection of liberty.
Compulsory taxation of individuals, such as income tax, is often justified on grounds including territorial sovereignty, and the social contract.
Defenders of business taxation argue that it is an efficient method of
taxing income that ultimately flows to individuals, or that separate
taxation of business
is justified on the grounds that commercial activity necessarily
involves use of publicly established and maintained economic
infrastructure, and that businesses are in effect charged for this use. Georgist economists argue that all of the economic rent
collected from natural resources (land, mineral extraction, fishing
quotas, etc.) is unearned income, and belongs to the community rather
than any individual. They advocate a high tax (the "Single Tax") on land
and other natural resources to return this unearned income to the
state, but no other taxes.
Opposition
Because payment of tax is compulsory and enforced by the legal system, rather than voluntary like crowdfunding, some political philosophies view taxation as theft, extortion, (or as slavery, or as a violation of property rights), or tyranny, accusing the government of levying taxes via force and coercive means. Voluntaryists, individualist anarchists, Objectivists, anarcho-capitalists, and libertarians see taxation as government aggression.
The view that democracy legitimizes taxation is rejected by those who
argue that all forms of government, including laws chosen by democratic
means, are fundamentally oppressive. According to Ludwig von Mises, "society as a whole" should not make such decisions, due to methodological individualism. Libertarian opponents of taxation claim that governmental protection, such as police and defense forces might be replaced by market alternatives such as private defense agencies, arbitration agencies or voluntary contributions.
Socialist view
Karl Marx assumed that taxation would be unnecessary after the advent of communism and looked forward to the "withering away of the state".
In socialist economies such as that of China, taxation played a minor
role, since most government income was derived from the ownership of
enterprises, and it was argued by some that monetary taxation was not
necessary.
While the morality of taxation is sometimes questioned, most arguments
about taxation revolve around the degree and method of taxation and
associated government spending, not taxation itself.
Choice
Tax choice is the theory that taxpayers should have more control with
how their individual taxes are allocated. If taxpayers could choose
which government organizations received their taxes, opportunity cost decisions would integrate their partial knowledge. For example, a taxpayer who allocated more of his taxes on public education would have less to allocate on public healthcare. Supporters argue that allowing taxpayers to demonstrate their preferences would help ensure that the government succeeds at efficiently producing the public goods that taxpayers truly value. This would end real estate speculation, business cycles, unemployment and distribute wealth much more evenly. Joseph Stiglitz's Henry George Theorem predicts its sufficiency because—as George also noted—public spending raises land value.
Geoist View
Geoists (Georgists and geolibertarians) state that taxation should primarily collect economic rent, in particular the value of land, for both reasons of economic efficiency as well as morality. The efficiency of using economic rent for taxation is (as economists agree) due to the fact that such taxation cannot be passed on and does not create any dead-weight loss, and that it removes the incentive to speculate on land. Its morality is based on the Geoist premise that private property is justified for products of labour but not for land and natural resources.
Economist and social reformer Henry George opposed sales taxes and protective tariffs for their negative impact on trade.
He also believed in the right of each person to the fruits of their own
labour and productive investment. Therefore, income from labour and proper capital should remain untaxed. For this reason many Geoists—in particular those that call themselves geolibertarian—share the view with libertarians that these types of taxation (but not all) are immoral and even theft. George stated there should be one single tax: the Land Value Tax, which is considered both efficient and moral. Demand for specific land is dependent on nature, but even more so on
the presence of communities, trade, and government infrastructure,
particularly in urban environments. Therefore, the economic rent
of land is not the product of one particular individual and it may be
claimed for public expenses. According to George, this would end real estate bubbles, business cycles, unemployment and distribute wealth much more evenly. Joseph Stiglitz's Henry George Theorem predicts its sufficiency for financing public goods because those raise land value.
John Locke
stated that whenever labour is mixed with natural resources, such as is
the case with improved land, private property is justified under the proviso that there must be enough other natural resources of the same quality available to others. Geoists state that the Lockean proviso is violated wherever land value
is greater than zero. Therefore, under the assumed principle of equal
rights of all people to natural resources, the occupier of any such land
must compensate the rest of society to the amount of that value. For
this reason, geoists generally believe that such payment cannot be regarded as a true 'tax', but rather a compensation or fee. This means that while Geoists also regard taxation as an instrument of social justice, contrary to social democrats and social liberals they do not regard it as an instrument of redistribution but rather a 'predistribution' or simply a correct distribution of the commons.
Modern geoists note that land in the classical economic meaning of the word referred to all natural resources, and thus also includes resources such as mineral deposits, water bodies and the electromagnetic spectrum, to which privileged access also generates economic rent that must be compensated. Under the same reasoning most of them also consider pigouvian taxes as compensation for environmental damage or privilege as acceptable and even necessary.
Theories
Laffer curve
In economics,
the Laffer curve is a theoretical representation of the relationship
between government revenue raised by taxation and all possible rates of
taxation. It is used to illustrate the concept of taxable income
elasticity (that taxable income will change in response to changes in the rate of taxation). The curve is constructed by thought experiment.
First, the amount of tax revenue raised at the extreme tax rates of 0%
and 100% is considered. It is clear that a 0% tax rate raises no
revenue, but the Laffer curve hypothesis is that a 100% tax rate will
also generate no revenue because at such a rate there is no longer any
incentive for a rational taxpayer to earn any income, thus the revenue
raised will be 100% of nothing. If both a 0% rate and 100% rate of
taxation generate no revenue, it follows from the extreme value theorem
that there must exist at least one rate in between where tax revenue
would be a maximum. The Laffer curve is typically represented as a graph
which starts at 0% tax, zero revenue, rises to a maximum rate of
revenue raised at an intermediate rate of taxation and then falls again
to zero revenue at a 100% tax rate.
One potential result of the Laffer curve is that increasing tax
rates beyond a certain point will become counterproductive for raising
further tax revenue. A hypothetical Laffer curve for any given economy
can only be estimated and such estimates are sometimes controversial. The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics reports that estimates of revenue-maximizing tax rates have varied widely, with a mid-range of around 70%.
Optimal
Most governments take revenue which exceeds that which can be
provided by non-distortionary taxes or through taxes which give a double
dividend. Optimal taxation theory is the branch of economics that
considers how taxes can be structured to give the least deadweight
costs, or to give the best outcomes in terms of social welfare. The Ramsey problem deals with minimizing deadweight costs. Because deadweight costs are related to the elasticity
of supply and demand for a good, it follows that putting the highest
tax rates on the goods for which there is most inelastic supply and
demand will result in the least overall deadweight costs. Some
economists sought to integrate optimal tax theory with the social welfare function,
which is the economic expression of the idea that equality is valuable
to a greater or lesser extent. If individuals experience diminishing returns from income, then the optimum distribution of income for society involves a progressive income tax. Mirrlees optimal income tax
is a detailed theoretical model of the optimum progressive income tax
along these lines. Over the last years the validity of the theory of
optimal taxation was discussed by many political economists.
Rates
Taxes are most often levied as a percentage, called the tax rate. An important distinction when talking about tax rates is to distinguish between the marginal rate and the effective tax rate.
The effective rate is the total tax paid divided by the total amount
the tax is paid on, while the marginal rate is the rate paid on the next
dollar of income earned. For example, if income is taxed on a formula
of 5% from $0 up to $50,000, 10% from $50,000 to $100,000, and 15% over
$100,000, a taxpayer with income of $175,000 would pay a total of $18,750 in taxes.
- Tax calculation
- (0.05*50,000) + (0.10*50,000) + (0.15*75,000) = 18,750
- The "effective rate" would be 10.7%:
- 18,750/175,000 = 0.107
- The "marginal rate" would be 15%.