The iron law of oligarchy is a political theory, first developed by the German sociologist Robert Michels in his 1911 book, Political Parties. It asserts that rule by an elite, or oligarchy,
is inevitable as an "iron law" within any democratic organization as
part of the "tactical and technical necessities" of organization.
Michels's theory states that all complex organizations,
regardless of how democratic they are when started, eventually develop
into oligarchies. Michels observed that since no sufficiently large and
complex organization can function purely as a direct democracy, power
within an organization will always get delegated to individuals within
that group, elected or otherwise.
Using anecdotes from political parties and trade unions
struggling to operate democratically to build his argument in 1911,
Michels addressed the application of this law to representative
democracy, and stated: "Who says organization, says oligarchy."
He went on to state that "Historical evolution mocks all the
prophylactic measures that have been adopted for the prevention of
oligarchy."
According to Michels all organizations eventually come to be run
by a "leadership class", who often function as paid administrators,
executives, spokespersons or political strategists for the organization.
Far from being "servants of the masses", Michels argues this
"leadership class," rather than the organization's membership, will
inevitably grow to dominate the organization's power structures.
By controlling who has access to information, those in power can
centralize their power successfully, often with little accountability,
due to the apathy, indifference and non-participation most rank and file
members have in relation to their organization's decision-making
processes. Michels argues that democratic attempts to hold leadership
positions accountable are prone to fail, since with power comes the ability to reward loyalty,
the ability to control information about the organization, and the
ability to control what procedures the organization follows when making
decisions. All of these mechanisms can be used to strongly influence
the outcome of any decisions made 'democratically' by members.
Michels stated that the official goal of representative democracy
of eliminating elite rule was impossible, that representative democracy
is a façade legitimizing the rule of a particular elite, and that elite rule, which he refers to as oligarchy, is inevitable. Later Michels migrated to Italy and joined Benito Mussolini's Fascist Party,
as he believed this was the next legitimate step of modern societies.
The thesis became popular once more in post-war America with the
publication of Union Democracy: The Internal Politics of the International Typographical Union (1956) and during the red scare brought about by McCarthyism.
History
In 1911 Robert Michels argued that paradoxically
the socialist parties of Europe, despite their democratic ideology and
provisions for mass participation, seemed to be dominated by their
leaders just like traditional conservative parties. Michels' conclusion was that the problem lay in the very nature of organizations. The more liberal
and democratic modern era allowed the formation of organizations with
innovative and revolutionary goals, but as such organizations become
more complex, they became less and less democratic and revolutionary.
Michels formulated the "Iron Law of Oligarchy": "Who says organization,
says oligarchy."
At the time Michels formulated his Law, he was an anarcho-syndicalist. He later became an important ideologue of Benito Mussolini's fascist regime in Italy, teaching economics at the University of Perugia.
Reasons
Michels
stressed several factors that underlie the Iron Law of Oligarchy. Darcy
K. Leach summarized them briefly as: "Bureaucracy happens. If
bureaucracy happens, power rises. Power corrupts." Any large organization, Michels pointed out, has to create a bureaucracy
in order to maintain its efficiency as it becomes larger—many decisions
have to be made daily that cannot be made by large numbers of
disorganized people. For the organization to function effectively,
centralization has to occur and power will end up in the hands of a few.
Those few—the oligarchy—will use all means necessary to preserve and
further increase their power.
According to Michels, this process is further compounded as
delegation is necessary in any large organization, as
thousands—sometimes hundreds of thousands—of members cannot make
decisions via participatory democracy. This has to-date been dictated by the lack of technological means for large numbers of people to meet and debate, and also by matters related to crowd psychology,
as Michels argued that people feel a need to be led. Delegation,
however, leads to specialization—to the development of knowledge bases,
skills and resources among a leadership—which further alienates the
leadership from the rank and file and entrenches the leadership in
office.
Bureaucratization and specialization are the driving processes behind the Iron Law. They result in the rise of a group of professional administrators in a hierarchical organization, which in turn leads to the rationalization and routinization of authority and decision-making, a process described first and perhaps best by Max Weber, later by John Kenneth Galbraith, and to a lesser and more cynical extent by the Peter Principle.
Bureaucracy by design leads to centralization of power by the
leaders. Leaders also have control over sanctions and rewards. They tend
to promote those who share their opinions, which inevitably leads to
self-perpetuating oligarchy. People achieve leadership positions because
they have above-average political skill.
As they advance in their careers, their power and prestige increases.
Leaders control the information that flows down the channels of
communication, censoring what they do not want the rank-and-file to
know. Leaders will also dedicate significant resources to persuade the
rank-and-file of the rightness of their views. This is compatible with
most societies: people are taught to obey those in positions of
authority. Therefore, the rank and file show little initiative, and wait
for the leaders to exercise their judgment and issue directives to
follow.
Implications
The
"iron law of oligarchy" states that all forms of organization,
regardless of how democratic they may be at the start, will eventually
and inevitably develop oligarchic
tendencies, thus making true democracy practically and theoretically
impossible, especially in large groups and complex organizations. The
relative structural fluidity in a small-scale democracy succumbs to
"social viscosity" in a large-scale organization. According to the "iron
law," democracy and large-scale organization are incompatible.
Examples and exceptions
An example that Michels used in his book was Germany's Social Democratic Party.
The size and complexity of a group or organization is important to the Iron Law as well. During the 1970s and early 1980s, the Green Party of Germany made a conscious effort to break the Iron Law.
Anyone could be or could remove a party official. There were no
permanent offices or officers. Even the smallest, most routine decisions
could be put up for discussion and to a vote. When the party was small,
these anti-oligarchic measures enjoyed some success. But as the
organization grew larger and the party became more successful, the need
to effectively compete in elections, raise funds, run large rallies and
demonstrations and work with other political parties once elected, led
the Greens to adopt more conventional structures and practices.
Labour Unions and Lipset's Union Democracy
One of the best known exceptions to the iron law of oligarchy was the now defunct International Typographical Union, described by Seymour Martin Lipset in his 1956 book, Union Democracy.
Lipset suggests a number of factors that existed in the ITU that are
allegedly responsible for countering this tendency toward bureaucratic
oligarchy. The first and perhaps most important has to do with the way
the union was founded. Unlike many other unions (e.g., the CIO's United Steel Workers of America
(USWA), and numerous other craft unions) which were organized from the
top down, the ITU had a number of large, strong, local unions who valued
their autonomy,
which existed long before the international was formed. This local
autonomy was strengthened by the economy of the printing industry which
operated in largely local and regional markets, with little competition
from other geographical areas. Large locals continued to jealously guard
this autonomy against encroachments by international officers. Second,
the existence of factions helped place a check on the oligarchic
tendencies that existed at the national headquarters. Leaders that are
unchecked tend to develop larger salaries and more sumptuous lifestyles,
making them unwilling to go back to their previous jobs. But with a
powerful out faction ready to expose profligacy, no leaders dared take
overly generous personal remuneration. These two factors were compelling
in the ITU case.
Lipset and his collaborators also cite a number of other factors
which are specific to craft unions in general and the printing crafts in
particular, including the homogeneity of the membership, with respect
to their work and lifestyles, their identification with their craft,
their more middle class lifestyle and pay. For this latter point he
draws upon Aristotle
who argued that a democratic polity was most likely where there was a
large, stable middle class, and the extremes of wealth and poverty were
not great. Finally, the authors note the irregular work hours which led
shopmates to spend more of their leisure time together. These latter
factors are less persuasive, since they do not apply to many industrial
forms of organization, where the greatest amount of trade union
democracy has developed in recent times.
University Student Unions
Titus Gregory uses Michels "iron law" to describe how the democratic centralist structure of the Canadian Federation of Students, consisting of individual student unions, encourages oligarchy.
Titus Gregory argues that University Students' union
today "exhibit both oligarchical and democratic tendencies." Unlike
unions they have an ideologically diverse membership, and frequently
have competitive democratic elections covered by independent campus
media who guard their independence. These factors are strongly
democratizing influences, creating conditions similar to those described
by Lipset about the ITU. However, Gregory argues student unions can
also be highly undemocratic and oligarchical as a result of the
transient membership of the students involved. Every year between one
quarter and one half of the membership turns over, and Gregory argues
this creates a situation where elected student leaders become dependent
on student union staff for institutional memory and guidance. Since
many students' unions extract compulsory fees from their transient
membership, and many smaller colleges and/or commuter campus can extract
this money with little accountability, oligarchical behaviour becomes
encouraged. For example, Gregory points out how often student union
election rules "operate under tyrannical rules and regulations" that are
used frequently by those in power to disqualify or exclude would-be
election challengers. Gregory concludes that students' unions can
"resist the iron law of oligarchy" if they have "an engaged student
community", an "independent student media," a "strong tradition of
freedom of information," and an "unbiased elections authority" capable
of administrating elections fairly.
Wikipedia
Research by Bradi Heaberlin and Simon DeDeo has found that the evolution of Wikipedia's network of norms over time is consistent with the iron law of oligarchy.
Their quantitative analysis is based on data-mining over a decade of
article and user information. It shows the emergence of an oligarchy
derived from competencies in five significant "clusters":
administration, article quality, collaboration, formatting, and content
policy. Heaberlin and DeDeo note, "The encyclopedia’s core norms
address universal principles, such as neutrality, verifiability,
civility, and consensus. The ambiguity and interpretability of these
abstract concepts may drive them to decouple from each other over time."
Other
The Iron Law of Oligarchy is similar to the concept in The Theory and Practice of Oligarchical Collectivism, a fictional book in the dystopian novel Nineteen Eighty-Four (1949) by George Orwell. The book begins:
Throughout recorded time, and probably since the end of the Neolithic Age, there have been three kinds of people in the world, the High, the Middle, and the Low. They have been subdivided in many ways, they have borne countless different names, and their relative numbers, as well as their attitude towards one another, have varied from age to age: but the essential structure of society has never altered. Even after enormous upheavals and seemingly irrevocable changes, the same pattern has always reasserted itself, just as a gyroscope will always return to equilibrium, however far it is pushed one way or the other.