In economics, economic rent is any payment to an owner or factor of production in excess of the costs needed to bring that factor into production. In classical economics, economic rent is any payment made (including imputed value) or benefit received for non-produced inputs such as location (land) and for assets formed by creating official privilege over natural opportunities (e.g., patents). In the moral economy of neoclassical economics, economic rent includes income gained by labor or state beneficiaries of other "contrived" (assuming the market is natural, and does not come about by state and social contrivance) exclusivity, such as labor guilds and unofficial corruption.
In the moral economy of the economics tradition broadly, economic rent is opposed to producer surplus, or normal profit, both of which are theorized to involve productive human action. Economic rent is also independent of opportunity cost, unlike economic profit, where opportunity cost is an essential component. Economic rent is viewed as unearned revenue while economic profit is a narrower term describing surplus income earned by choosing between risk-adjusted alternatives. Unlike economic profit, economic rent cannot be theoretically eliminated by competition because any actions the recipient of the income may take such as improving the object to be rented will then change the total income to contract rent. Still, the total income is made up of economic profit (earned) plus economic rent (unearned).
For a produced commodity, economic rent may be due to the legal ownership of a patent (a politically enforced right to the use of a process or ingredient). For education and occupational licensing, it is the knowledge, performance, and ethical standards, as well as the cost of permits and licenses that are collectively controlled as to their number, regardless of the competence and willingness of those who wish to compete on price alone in the area being licensed. In regard to labor, economic rent can be created by the existence of mass education, labor laws, state social reproduction supports, democracy, guilds, and labor unions (e.g., higher pay for some workers, where collective action creates a scarcity of such workers, as opposed to an ideal condition where labor competes with other factors of production on price alone). For most other production, including agriculture and extraction, economic rent is due to a scarcity (uneven distribution) of natural resources (e.g., land, oil, or minerals).
When economic rent is privatized, the recipient of economic rent is referred to as a rentier.
By contrast, in production theory, if there is no exclusivity and there is perfect competition, there are no economic rents, as competition drives prices down to their floor.
Economic rent is different from other unearned and passive income, including contract rent. This distinction has important implications for public revenue and tax policy. As long as there is sufficient accounting profit, governments can collect a portion of economic rent for the purpose of public finance. For example, economic rent can be collected by a government as royalties or extraction fees in the case of resources such as minerals and oil and gas.
Historically, theories of rent have typically applied to rent received by different factor owners within a single economy. Hossein Mahdavy was the first to introduce the concept of "external rent", whereby one economy received rent from other economies.
Definitions
According to Robert Tollison
(1982), economic rents are "excess returns" above the "normal levels"
that are generated in competitive markets. More specifically, a rent is
"a return in excess of the resource owner's opportunity cost".
Henry George, best known for his proposal for a single tax on land,
defines rent as "the part of the produce that accrues to the owners of
land (or other natural capabilities) by virtue of ownership" and as "the
share of wealth given to landowners because they have an exclusive
right to the use of those natural capabilities."
The law professors Lucian Bebchuk and Jesse Fried define the term as "extra returns that firms or individuals obtain due to their positional advantages."
In simple terms, economic rent is an excess where there is no enterprise or costs of production.
Classical rent (land rent)
In political economy, including physiocracy, classical economics, Georgism, and other schools of economic thought, land is recognized as an inelastic factor of production. Land, in this sense, means exclusive access rights to any natural opportunity. Rent is the share paid to freeholders for allowing production on the land they control.
As soon as the land of any country has all become private property, the landlords, like all other men, love to reap where they never sowed, and demand a rent even for its natural produce. The wood of the forest, the grass of the field, and all the natural fruits of the earth, which, when land was in common, cost the labourer only the trouble of gathering them, come, even to him, to have an additional price fixed upon them. He must then pay for the licence to gather them; and must give up to the landlord a portion of what his labour either collects or produces. This portion, or, what comes to the same thing, the price of this portion, constitutes the rent of land ....
David Ricardo
is credited with the first clear and comprehensive analysis of
differential land rent and the associated economic relationships.
Johann Heinrich von Thünen
was influential in developing the spatial analysis of rents, which
highlighted the importance of centrality and transport. Simply put, it
was density of population, increasing the profitability of commerce and
providing for the division and specialization of labor, that commanded
higher municipal rents. These high rents determined that land in a
central city would not be allocated to farming but be allocated instead
to more profitable residential or commercial uses.
Observing that a tax on the unearned rent of land would not distort economic activities, Henry George proposed that publicly collected land rents (land value taxation) should be the primary (or only) source of public revenue, though he also advocated public ownership, taxation, and regulation of natural monopolies and monopolies of scale that cannot be eliminated by regulation.
Neoclassical Paretian rent
Neoclassical economics extends the concept of rent to include factors other than natural resource rents.
- "The excess earnings over the amount necessary to keep the factor in its current occupation."
- "The difference between what a factor of production is paid and how much it would need to be paid to remain in its current use."
- "A return over and above opportunity costs, or the normal return necessary to keep a resource in its current use."
The labeling of this version of rent as "Paretian" may be a misnomer in that Vilfredo Pareto, the economist for whom this kind of rent was named, may or may not have proffered any conceptual formulation of rent.
Monopoly rent
Monopoly
rent refers to those economic rents derived from monopolies, which can
result from (1) denial of access to an asset or (2) the unique qualities
of an asset. Examples of monopoly rent include: rents associated from legally enforced knowledge monopolies derived from intellectual property like patents or copyrights; rents associated with 'de facto' monopolies of companies like Microsoft and Intel
who control the underlying standards in an industry or product line
(e.g. Microsoft Office); rents associated with 'natural monopolies' of
public or private utilities (e.g. telephone, electricity, railways,
etc.); and rents associated with network effects of platform
technologies controlled by companies like Facebook, Google, or Amazon.
Labour
The generalization of the concept of rent to include opportunity cost
has served to highlight the role of political barriers in creating and
privatizing rents. For example, a person seeking to become a member of a
medieval guild
makes a huge investment in training and education, which has limited
potential application outside of that guild. In a competitive market,
the wages of a member of the guild would be set so that the expected net
return on the investment in training would be just enough to justify
making the investment. In a sense, the required investment is a natural
barrier to entry, discouraging some would-be members from making the
necessary investment in training to enter the competitive market for the
services of the guild. This is a natural "free market" self-limiting
control on the number of guild members and/or the cost of training
necessitated by certification. Some of those who would have opted for a
particular guild may decide to join a different guild or occupation.
However, a political restriction on the number of people entering
into the competitive market for services of the guild has the effect of
raising the return on investments in the guild's training, especially
for those already practicing, by creating an artificial scarcity of
guild members. To the extent that a constraint on entrants to the guild
actually increases the returns to guild members as opposed to ensuring
competence, then the practice of limiting entrants to the field is a rent-seeking activity, and the excess return realized by the guild members is economic rent.
The same model explains the high wages in some modern professions
that have been able to both obtain legal protection from competition
and limit their membership, notably medical doctors, actuaries, and lawyers. In countries where the creation of new universities is limited by legal charter, such as the UK, it also applies to professors.
It may also apply to careers that are inherently competitive in the
sense that there is a fixed number of slots, such as football league
positions, music charts, or urban territory for illegal drug selling.
These jobs are characterised by the existence of a small number of rich
members of the guild, along with a much larger surrounding of poor
people competing against each other under very poor conditions as they
"pay their dues" to try to join the guild. (Reference: "Freakonomics:
Why do drug dealers live with their Moms?").
Terminology relating to rent
- Gross rent
- Gross rent refers to the rent paid for the services of land and the capital invested on it. It consists of economic rent, interest on capital invested for improvement of land, and reward for the risk taken by the landlord in investing his or her capital.
- Scarcity rent
- Scarcity rent refers to the price paid for the use of homogeneous land when its supply is limited in relation to demand. If all units of land are homogeneous but demand exceeds supply, all land will earn economic rent by virtue of its scarcity.
- Differential rent
- Differential rent refers to the rent that arises owing to differences in fertility of land. The surplus that arises due to difference between the marginal and intra-marginal land is the differential rent. It is generally accrued under conditions of extensive land cultivation. The term was first proposed by David Ricardo.
- Contract rent
- Contract rent refers to rent that is mutually agreed upon between the landowner and the user. It may be equal to the economic rent of the factor.
- Information rent
- Information rent is rent an agent derives from having information not provided to the principal.