Feudalism was a combination of legal and military customs in medieval Europe
that flourished between the 9th and 15th centuries. Broadly defined, it
was a way of structuring society around relationships derived from the
holding of land in exchange for service or labour.
Although derived from the Latin word feodum or feudum (fief), then in use, the term feudalism and the system it describes were not conceived of as a formal political system by the people living in the Middle Ages. In its classic definition, by François-Louis Ganshof (1944), feudalism
describes a set of reciprocal legal and military obligations among the
warrior nobility revolving around the three key concepts of lords, vassals and fiefs.
A broader definition of feudalism, as described by Marc Bloch (1939), includes not only the obligations of the warrior nobility but also those of all three estates of the realm: the nobility, the clergy, and the peasantry bound by manorialism; this is sometimes referred to as a "feudal society". Since the publication of Elizabeth A. R. Brown's "The Tyranny of a Construct" (1974) and Susan Reynolds's Fiefs and Vassals
(1994), there has been ongoing inconclusive discussion among medieval
historians as to whether feudalism is a useful construct for
understanding medieval society.
Definition
There is no commonly accepted modern definition of feudalism, at least among scholars. The adjective feudal was coined in the 17th century, and the noun feudalism, often used in a political and propaganda context, was not coined until the 19th century, from the French féodalité (feudality), itself an 18th-century creation.
In a classic definition by François-Louis Ganshof (1944), feudalism
describes a set of reciprocal legal and military obligations among the
warrior nobility, revolving around the three key concepts of lords, vassals and fiefs, though Ganshof himself noted that his treatment related only to the "narrow, technical, legal sense of the word".
A broader definition, as described in Marc Bloch's Feudal Society (1939), includes not only the obligations of the warrior nobility but those of all three estates of the realm: the nobility, the clergy, and those living by their labour, most directly the peasantry bound by manorialism; this order is often referred to as "feudal society", echoing Bloch's usage.
Since the publication of Elizabeth A. R. Brown's "The Tyranny of a Construct" (1974) and Susan Reynolds's Fiefs and Vassals (1994),
there has been ongoing inconclusive discussion among medieval
historians as to whether feudalism is a useful construct for
understanding medieval society.
Outside a European context, the concept of feudalism is often used only by analogy (called semi-feudal), most often in discussions of feudal Japan under the shōguns, and sometimes medieval and Gondarine Ethiopia. However, some have taken the feudalism analogy further, seeing feudalism (or traces of it) in places as diverse as Spring and Autumn period in China, ancient Egypt, the Parthian empire, the Indian subcontinent and the Antebellum and Jim Crow American South.
The term feudalism has also been applied—often
inappropriately or pejoratively—to non-Western societies where
institutions and attitudes similar to those of medieval Europe are perceived to prevail. Some historians and political theorists believe that the term feudalism
has been deprived of specific meaning by the many ways it has been
used, leading them to reject it as a useful concept for understanding
society.
Etymology
The term "féodal" was used in 17th-century French legal treatises (1614) and translated into English legal treatises as an adjective, such as "feodal government".
In the 18th century, Adam Smith, seeking to describe economic systems, effectively coined the forms "feudal government" and "feudal system" in his book Wealth of Nations (1776). In the 19th century the adjective "feudal" evolved into a noun: "feudalism". The term feudalism
is recent, first appearing in French in 1823, Italian in 1827, English
in 1839, and in German in the second half of the 19th century.
The term "feudal" or "feodal" is derived from the medieval Latin word feodum. The etymology of feodum is complex with multiple theories, some suggesting a Germanic origin (the most widely held view) and others suggesting an Arabic origin. Initially in medieval Latin European documents, a land grant in exchange for service was called a beneficium (Latin). Later, the term feudum, or feodum, began to replace beneficium in the documents. The first attested instance of this is from 984, although more primitive forms were seen up to one-hundred years earlier. The origin of the feudum and why it replaced beneficium has not been well established, but there are multiple theories, described below.
The most widely held theory was proposed by Johan Hendrik Caspar Kern in 1870, being supported by, amongst others, William Stubbs and Marc Bloch. Kern derived the word from a putative Frankish term *fehu-ôd, in which *fehu means "cattle" and -ôd means "goods", implying "a moveable object of value."
Bloch explains that by the beginning of the 10th century it was common
to value land in monetary terms but to pay for it with moveable objects
of equivalent value, such as arms, clothing, horses or food. This was
known as feos, a term that took on the general meaning of paying
for something in lieu of money. This meaning was then applied to land
itself, in which land was used to pay for fealty, such as to a vassal.
Thus the old word feos meaning movable property changed little by little to feus meaning the exact opposite: landed property.
Another theory was put forward by Archibald R. Lewis. Lewis said the origin of 'fief' is not feudum (or feodum), but rather foderum, the earliest attested use being in Astronomus's Vita Hludovici (840). In that text is a passage about Louis the Pious that says annona militaris quas vulgo foderum vocant, which can be translated as "Louis forbade that military provender (which they popularly call "fodder") be furnished.."
Another theory by Alauddin Samarrai suggests an Arabic origin, from fuyū (the plural of fay,
which literally means "the returned", and was used especially for 'land
that has been conquered from enemies that did not fight'). Samarrai's theory is that early forms of 'fief' include feo, feu, feuz, feuum and others, the plurality of forms strongly suggesting origins from a loanword. The first use of these terms is in Languedoc, one of the least Germanic areas of Europe and bordering Muslim Spain. Further, the earliest use of feuum (as a replacement for beneficium) can be dated to 899, the same year a Muslim base at Fraxinetum (La Garde-Freinet) in Provence was established. It is possible, Samarrai says, that French scribes, writing in Latin, attempted to transliterate the Arabic word fuyū (the plural of fay), which was being used by the Muslim invaders and occupiers at the time, resulting in a plurality of forms – feo, feu, feuz, feuum and others – from which eventually feudum
derived. Samarrai, however, also advises to handle this theory with
care, as Medieval and Early Modern Muslim scribes often used
etymologically "fanciful roots" in order to claim the most outlandish
things to be of Arabian or Muslim origin.
History
Feudalism, in its various forms, usually emerged as a result of the decentralization of an empire: especially in the Carolingian Empire, which lacked the bureaucratic infrastructure necessary to support cavalry
without the ability to allocate land to these mounted troops. Mounted
soldiers began to secure a system of hereditary rule over their
allocated land and their power over the territory came to encompass the
social, political, judicial, and economic spheres.
These acquired powers significantly diminished unitary power
in these empires. Only when the infrastructure existed to maintain
unitary power—as with the European monarchies—did feudalism begin to
yield to this new power structure and eventually disappear.
Classic feudalism
The classic François-Louis Ganshof version of feudalism
describes a set of reciprocal legal and military obligations among the
warrior nobility, revolving around the three key concepts of lords, vassals and fiefs.
A lord was in broad terms a noble who held land, a vassal was a person
who was granted possession of the land by the lord, and the land was
known as a fief. In exchange for the use of the fief and protection by
the lord, the vassal would provide some sort of service to the lord.
There were many varieties of feudal land tenure,
consisting of military and non-military service. The obligations and
corresponding rights between lord and vassal concerning the fief form
the basis of the feudal relationship.
Vassalage
Before a lord could grant land (a fief) to someone, he had to make
that person a vassal. This was done at a formal and symbolic ceremony
called a commendation ceremony, which was composed of the two-part act of homage and oath of fealty.
During homage, the lord and vassal entered into a contract in which the
vassal promised to fight for the lord at his command, whilst the lord
agreed to protect the vassal from external forces. Fealty comes from the Latin fidelitas and denotes the fidelity
owed by a vassal to his feudal lord. "Fealty" also refers to an oath
that more explicitly reinforces the commitments of the vassal made
during homage. Such an oath follows homage.
Once the commendation ceremony was complete, the lord and vassal
were in a feudal relationship with agreed obligations to one another.
The vassal's principal obligation to the lord was to "aid", or military
service. Using whatever equipment the vassal could obtain by virtue of
the revenues from the fief, the vassal was responsible to answer calls
to military service on behalf of the lord. This security of military
help was the primary reason the lord entered into the feudal
relationship. In addition, the vassal could have other obligations to
his lord, such as attendance at his court, whether manorial, baronial,
both termed court baron, or at the king's court.
It could also involve the vassal providing "counsel", so that if the
lord faced a major decision he would summon all his vassals and hold a
council. At the level of the manor
this might be a fairly mundane matter of agricultural policy, but also
included sentencing by the lord for criminal offences, including capital
punishment in some cases. Concerning the king's feudal court, such
deliberation could include the question of declaring war. These are
examples; depending on the period of time and location in Europe, feudal
customs and practices varied.
The "Feudal Revolution" in France
In
its origin, the feudal grant of land had been seen in terms of a
personal bond between lord and vassal, but with time and the
transformation of fiefs into hereditary holdings, the nature of the
system came to be seen as a form of "politics of land" (an expression
used by the historian Marc Bloch).
The 11th century in France saw what has been called by historians a
"feudal revolution" or "mutation" and a "fragmentation of powers"
(Bloch) that was unlike the development of feudalism in England or Italy
or Germany in the same period or later: Counties and duchies began to break down into smaller holdings as castellans
and lesser seigneurs took control of local lands, and (as comital
families had done before them) lesser lords usurped/privatized a wide
range of prerogatives and rights of the state, most importantly the
highly profitable rights of justice, but also travel dues, market dues,
fees for using woodlands, obligations to use the lord's mill, etc. (what Georges Duby called collectively the "seigneurie banale"). Power in this period became more personal.
This "fragmentation of powers" was not, however, systematic
throughout France, and in certain counties (such as Flanders, Normandy,
Anjou, Toulouse), counts were able to maintain control of their lands
into the 12th century or later.
Thus, in some regions (like Normandy and Flanders), the vassal/feudal
system was an effective tool for ducal and comital control, linking
vassals to their lords; but in other regions, the system led to
significant confusion, all the more so as vassals could and frequently
did pledge themselves to two or more lords. In response to this, the
idea of a "liege lord" was developed (where the obligations to one lord are regarded as superior) in the 12th century.
End of European feudalism (1500–1850s)
Feudalism effectively ended by about 1500.
This was partly since the military shifted from armies consisting of
the nobility to professional fighters thus reducing the nobility's claim
on power, but also because the Black Death
reduced the nobility's hold over the lower classes. Vestiges of the
Feudal system hung on in France until the French Revolution, and the
system lingered on in parts of Central and Eastern Europe as late as the
1850s. Russia finally abolished serfdom in 1861.
Even when the original feudal relationships had disappeared,
there were many institutional remnants of feudalism left in place.
Historian Georges Lefebvre explains how at an early stage of the French Revolution,
on just one night of August 4, 1789, France abolished the long-lasting
remnants of the feudal order. It announced, "The National Assembly
abolishes the feudal system entirely." Lefebvre explains:
Without debate the Assembly enthusiastically adopted equality of taxation and redemption of all manorial rights except for those involving personal servitude — which were to be abolished without indemnification. Other proposals followed with the same success: the equality of legal punishment, admission of all to public office, abolition of venality in office, conversion of the tithe into payments subject to redemption, freedom of worship, prohibition of plural holding of benefices.... Privileges of provinces and towns were offered as a last sacrifice.
Originally the peasants were supposed to pay for the release of
seigneurial dues; these dues affected more than a fourth of the farmland
in France and provided most of the income of the large landowners.
The majority refused to pay and in 1793 the obligation was cancelled.
Thus the peasants got their land free, and also no longer paid the tithe
to the church.
Feudal society
The phrase "feudal society" as defined by Marc Bloch
offers a wider definition than Ganshof's and includes within the feudal
structure not only the warrior aristocracy bound by vassalage, but also
the peasantry
bound by manorialism, and the estates of the Church. Thus the feudal
order embraces society from top to bottom, though the "powerful and
well-differentiated social group of the urban classes" came to occupy a
distinct position to some extent outside the classical feudal hierarchy.
Historiography
The idea of feudalism
was unknown and the system it describes was not conceived of as a
formal political system by the people living in the Medieval Period.
This section describes the history of the idea of feudalism, how the
concept originated among scholars and thinkers, how it changed over
time, and modern debates about its use.
Evolution of the concept
The
concept of a feudal state or period, in the sense of either a regime or
a period dominated by lords who possess financial or social power and
prestige, became widely held in the middle of the 18th century, as a
result of works such as Montesquieu's De L'Esprit des Lois (1748; published in English as The Spirit of the Laws), and Henri de Boulainvilliers’s Histoire des anciens Parlements de France (1737; published in English as An Historical Account of the Ancient Parliaments of France or States-General of the Kingdom, 1739). In the 18th century, writers of the Enlightenment wrote about feudalism to denigrate the antiquated system of the Ancien Régime, or French monarchy. This was the Age of Enlightenment when writers valued reason and the Middle Ages were viewed as the "Dark Ages".
Enlightenment authors generally mocked and ridiculed anything from the
"Dark Ages" including feudalism, projecting its negative characteristics
on the current French monarchy as a means of political gain. For them "feudalism" meant seigneurial privileges and prerogatives. When the French Constituent Assembly abolished the "feudal regime" in August 1789 this is what was meant.
Adam Smith
used the term "feudal system" to describe a social and economic system
defined by inherited social ranks, each of which possessed inherent
social and economic privileges and obligations. In such a system wealth
derived from agriculture, which was arranged not according to market
forces but on the basis of customary labour services owed by serfs to landowning nobles.
Karl Marx
Karl Marx
also used the term in the 19th century in his analysis of society's
economic and political development, describing feudalism (or more
usually feudal society or the feudal mode of production) as the order coming before capitalism. For Marx, what defined feudalism was the power of the ruling class (the aristocracy) in their control of arable land, leading to a class society based upon the exploitation of the peasants who farm these lands, typically under serfdom and principally by means of labour, produce and money rents. Marx thus defined feudalism primarily by its economic characteristics.
He also took it as a paradigm for understanding the
power-relationships between capitalists and wage-labourers in his own
time: ‘in pre-capitalist systems it was obvious that most people did not
control their own destiny — under feudalism, for instance, serfs had to
work for their lords. Capitalism seems different because people are in
theory free to work for themselves or for others as they choose. Yet
most workers have as little control over their lives as feudal serfs’. Some later Marxist theorists (e.g. Eric Wolf)
have applied this label to include non-European societies, grouping
feudalism together with Imperial Chinese and pre-Columbian Incan
societies as 'tributary'.
Later studies
In the late 19th and early 20th centuries, John Horace Round and Frederic William Maitland, both historians of medieval Britain, arrived at different conclusions as to the character of English society before the Norman Conquest
in 1066. Round argued that the Normans had brought feudalism with them
to England, while Maitland contended that its fundamentals were already
in place in Britain before 1066. The debate continues today, but a
consensus viewpoint is that England before the Conquest had commendation
(which embodied some of the personal elements in feudalism) while William the Conqueror
introduced a modified and stricter northern French feudalism to England
incorporating (1086) oaths of loyalty to the king by all who held by
feudal tenure, even the vassals of his principal vassals (holding by
feudal tenure meant that vassals must provide the quota of knights
required by the king or a money payment in substitution).
In the 20th century, two outstanding historians offered still more widely differing perspectives. The French historian Marc Bloch, arguably the most influential 20th-century medieval historian, approached feudalism not so much from a legal and military point of view but from a sociological one, presenting in Feudal Society
(1939; English 1961) a feudal order not limited solely to the nobility.
It is his radical notion that peasants were part of the feudal
relationship that sets Bloch apart from his peers: while the vassal
performed military service in exchange for the fief, the peasant
performed physical labour in return for protection – both are a form of
feudal relationship. According to Bloch, other elements of society can
be seen in feudal terms; all the aspects of life were centered on
"lordship", and so we can speak usefully of a feudal church structure, a
feudal courtly (and anti-courtly) literature, and a feudal economy.
In contradistinction to Bloch, the Belgian historian François-Louis Ganshof
defined feudalism from a narrow legal and military perspective, arguing
that feudal relationships existed only within the medieval nobility
itself. Ganshof articulated this concept in Qu'est-ce que la féodalité? ("What is feudalism?", 1944; translated in English as Feudalism). His classic definition of feudalism is widely accepted today among medieval scholars,
though questioned both by those who view the concept in wider terms and
by those who find insufficient uniformity in noble exchanges to support
such a model.
Although he was never formally a student in the circle of scholars around Marc Bloch and Lucien Febvre that came to be known as the Annales School, Georges Duby was an exponent of the Annaliste tradition. In a published version of his 1952 doctoral thesis entitled La société aux XIe et XIIe siècles dans la région mâconnaise (Society in the 11th and 12th centuries in the Mâconnais region), and working from the extensive documentary sources surviving from the Burgundian monastery of Cluny, as well as the dioceses of Mâcon and Dijon, Duby excavated the complex social and economic relationships among the individuals and institutions of the Mâconnais
region and charted a profound shift in the social structures of
medieval society around the year 1000. He argued that in early 11th
century, governing institutions—particularly comital courts established
under the Carolingian
monarchy—that had represented public justice and order in Burgundy
during the 9th and 10th centuries receded and gave way to a new feudal
order wherein independent aristocratic knights wielded power over
peasant communities through strong-arm tactics and threats of violence.
Challenges to the feudal model
In 1974, U.S. historian Elizabeth A. R. Brown rejected the label feudalism
as an anachronism that imparts a false sense of uniformity to the
concept. Having noted the current use of many, often contradictory,
definitions of feudalism, she argued that the word is only a
construct with no basis in medieval reality, an invention of modern
historians read back "tyrannically" into the historical record.
Supporters of Brown have suggested that the term should be expunged from
history textbooks and lectures on medieval history entirely. In Fiefs and Vassals: The Medieval Evidence Reinterpreted (1994), Susan Reynolds
expanded upon Brown's original thesis. Although some contemporaries
questioned Reynolds's methodology, other historians have supported it
and her argument. Reynolds argues:
- Too many models of feudalism used for comparisons, even by Marxists, are still either constructed on the 16th-century basis or incorporate what, in a Marxist view, must surely be superficial or irrelevant features from it. Even when one restricts oneself to Europe and to feudalism in its narrow sense it is extremely doubtful whether feudo-vassalic institutions formed a coherent bundle of institutions or concepts that were structurally separate from other institutions and concepts of the time.
The term feudal has also been applied to non-Western societies
in which institutions and attitudes similar to those of medieval Europe
are perceived to have prevailed. Japan has been extensively studied in this regard.
Friday notes that in the 21st century historians of Japan rarely
invoke feudalism; instead of looking at similarities, specialists
attempting comparative analysis concentrate on fundamental differences. Ultimately, critics say, the many ways the term feudalism has been used have deprived it of specific meaning, leading some historians and political theorists to reject it as a useful concept for understanding society.
Richard Abels notes that "Western Civilization and World Civilization textbooks now shy away from the term 'feudalism'."