One goal of microeconomics is to analyze the market mechanisms that establish relative prices
among goods and services and allocate limited resources among
alternative uses. Microeconomics shows conditions under which free
markets lead to desirable allocations. It also analyzes market failure, where markets fail to produce efficient results.
Microeconomics stands in contrast to macroeconomics, which involves "the sum total of economic activity, dealing with the issues of growth, inflation, and unemployment and with national policies relating to these issues". Microeconomics also deals with the effects of economic policies (such as changing taxation levels) on microeconomic behavior and thus on the aforementioned aspects of the economy. Particularly in the wake of the Lucas critique, much of modern macroeconomic theories has been built upon microfoundations—i.e. based upon basic assumptions about micro-level behavior.
Microeconomics stands in contrast to macroeconomics, which involves "the sum total of economic activity, dealing with the issues of growth, inflation, and unemployment and with national policies relating to these issues". Microeconomics also deals with the effects of economic policies (such as changing taxation levels) on microeconomic behavior and thus on the aforementioned aspects of the economy. Particularly in the wake of the Lucas critique, much of modern macroeconomic theories has been built upon microfoundations—i.e. based upon basic assumptions about micro-level behavior.
Assumptions and definitions
Microeconomic theory typically begins with the study of a single rational and utility maximizing individual. To economists, rationality means an individual possesses stable preferences that are both complete and transitive.
The technical assumption that preference relations are continuous is needed to ensure the existence of a utility function. Although microeconomic theory can continue without this assumption, it would make comparative statics impossible since there is no guarantee that the resulting utility function would be differentiable.
Microeconomic theory progresses by defining a competitive budget set which is a subset of the consumption set. It is at this point that economists make the technical assumption that preferences are locally non-satiated. Without the assumption of LNS (local non-satiation) there is no 100% guarantee but there would be a rational rise
in individual utility. With the necessary tools and assumptions in place the utility maximization problem (UMP) is developed.
The utility maximization problem is the heart of consumer theory. The utility maximization problem attempts to explain the action axiom
by imposing rationality axioms on consumer preferences and then
mathematically modeling and analyzing the consequences. The utility
maximization problem serves not only as the mathematical foundation of
consumer theory but as a metaphysical explanation of it as well. That is, the utility maximization problem is used by economists to not only explain what or how individuals make choices but why individuals make choices as well.
The utility maximization problem is a constrained optimization problem in which an individual seeks to maximize utility subject to a budget constraint. Economists use the extreme value theorem to guarantee that a solution to the utility maximization problem exists. That is, since the budget constraint
is both bounded and closed, a solution to the utility maximization
problem exists. Economists call the solution to the utility maximization
problem a Walrasian demand function or correspondence.
The utility maximization problem has so far been developed by
taking consumer tastes (i.e. consumer utility) as the primitive.
However, an alternative way to develop microeconomic theory is by taking
consumer choice as the primitive. This model of microeconomic theory is
referred to as revealed preference theory.
The theory of supply and demand usually assumes that markets are perfectly competitive.
This implies that there are many buyers and sellers in the market and
none of them have the capacity to significantly influence prices of
goods and services. In many real-life transactions, the assumption fails
because some individual buyers or sellers have the ability to influence
prices. Quite often, a sophisticated analysis is required to understand
the demand-supply equation of a good model. However, the theory works
well in situations meeting these assumptions.
Mainstream economics does not assume a priori that markets are preferable to other forms of social organization. In fact, much analysis is devoted to cases where market failures lead to resource allocation that is suboptimal and creates deadweight loss. A classic example of suboptimal resource allocation is that of a public good. In such cases, economists
may attempt to find policies that avoid waste, either directly by
government control, indirectly by regulation that induces market
participants to act in a manner consistent with optimal welfare, or by
creating "missing markets" to enable efficient trading where none had previously existed.
This is studied in the field of collective action and public choice theory. "Optimal welfare" usually takes on a Paretian norm, which is a mathematical application of the Kaldor–Hicks method. This can diverge from the Utilitarian goal of maximizing utility
because it does not consider the distribution of goods between people.
Market failure in positive economics (microeconomics) is limited in
implications without mixing the belief of the economist and their
theory.
The demand for various commodities by individuals is generally
thought of as the outcome of a utility-maximizing process, with each
individual trying to maximize their own utility under a budget constraint and a given consumption set.
Basic microeconomic concepts
The study of microeconomics involves several "key" areas:
Demand, supply, and equilibrium
Supply and demand is an economic model of price determination in a perfectly competitive market. It concludes that in a perfectly competitive market with no externalities, per unit taxes, or price controls, the unit price for a particular good
is the price at which the quantity demanded by consumers equals the
quantity supplied by producers. This price results in a stable economic equilibrium.
Measurement of elasticities
Elasticity is the measurement of how responsive an economic
variable is to a change in another variable. Elasticity can be
quantified as the ratio of the change
in one variable to the change in another variable, when the later
variable has a causal influence on the former. It is a tool for
measuring the responsiveness of a variable, or of the function that
determines it, to changes in causative variables in unitless ways.
Frequently used elasticities include price elasticity of demand, price elasticity of supply, income elasticity of demand, elasticity of substitution or constant elasticity of substitution between factors of production and elasticity of intertemporal substitution.
Consumer demand theory
Consumer demand theory relates preferences for the consumption of both goods
and services to the consumption expenditures; ultimately, this
relationship between preferences and consumption expenditures is used to
relate preferences to consumer demand curves. The link between personal preferences, consumption and the demand curve is one of the most closely studied relations in economics. It is a way of analyzing how consumers may achieve equilibrium between preferences and expenditures by maximizing utility subject to consumer budget constraints.
Theory of production
Production theory is the study of production, or the economic process of converting inputs into outputs. Production uses resources to create a good or service that is suitable for use, gift-giving in a gift economy, or exchange in a market economy. This can include manufacturing, storing, shipping, and packaging. Some economists define production broadly as all economic activity other than consumption. They see every commercial activity other than the final purchase as some form of production.
Costs of production
The cost-of-production theory of value states that the price
of an object or condition is determined by the sum of the cost of the
resources that went into making it. The cost can comprise any of the factors of production: labour, capital, land, entrepreneur. Technology can be viewed either as a form of fixed capital (e.g.
plant) or circulating capital (e.g.
intermediate goods).
In the mathematical model for the cost of production, the short-run total cost is equal to fixed cost plus total variable cost.
The fixed cost refers to the cost that is incurred regardless of how
much the firm produces. The variable cost is a function of the quantity
of an object being produced.
Opportunity cost
The economic idea of opportunity cost is closely related to
the idea of time constraints. You can do only one thing at a time, which
means that, inevitably, you’re always giving up other things.
The opportunity cost of any activity is the value of the
next-best alternative thing you may have done instead. Opportunity cost
depends only on the value of the next-best alternative. It doesn’t
matter whether you have 5 alternatives or 5,000.
Opportunity costs can tell you when not to do something as
well as when to do something. For example, you may like waffles, but
you like chocolate even more. If someone offers you only waffles, you’re
going to take it. But if you’re offered waffles or chocolate, you’re
going to take the chocolate. The opportunity cost of eating waffles is
sacrificing the chance to eat chocolate. Because the cost of not eating
the chocolate is higher than the benefits of eating the waffles, it
makes no sense to choose waffles. Of course, if you choose chocolate,
you’re still faced with the opportunity cost of giving up having
waffles. But you’re willing to do that because the waffle's opportunity
cost is lower than the benefits of the chocolate. Opportunity costs are
unavoidable constraints on behaviour because you have to decide what’s
best and give up the next-best alternative.
Market structure
The market structure can have several types of interacting market systems.
Different forms of markets are a feature of capitalism and market socialism, with advocates of state socialism often criticizing markets and aiming to substitute or replace markets with varying degrees of government-directed economic planning.
Competition acts as a regulatory mechanism for market systems,
with government providing regulations where the market cannot be
expected to regulate itself. One example of this is with regards to building codes,
which if absent in a purely competition regulated market system, might
result in several horrific injuries or deaths to be required before
companies would begin improving structural safety, as consumers may at
first not be as concerned or aware of safety issues to begin putting
pressure on companies to provide them, and companies would be motivated
not to provide proper safety features due to how it would cut into their
profits.
Some examples of markets:
- commodity markets
- insurance markets
- bond markets
- energy markets
- flea markets
- debt markets
- stock markets
- online auctions
- media exchange markets
- real-estate market.
Perfect competition
Perfect competition is a situation in which numerous small
firms producing identical products compete against each other in a given
industry. Perfect competition leads to firms producing the socially
optimal output level at the minimum possible cost per unit. Firms in
perfect competition are "price takers" (they do not have enough market power to profitably increase the price of their goods or services). A good example would be that of digital marketplaces, such as eBay,
on which many different sellers sell similar products to many different
buyers. Consumers in a perfect competitive market have perfect
knowledge about the products that are being sold in this market.
Imperfect competition
In economic theory, imperfect competition is a type of market structure showing some but not all features of competitive markets.
Monopolistic competition
Monopolistic competition is a situation in which many firms
with slightly different products compete. Production costs are above
what may be achieved by perfectly competitive firms, but society
benefits from the product differentiation. Examples of industries with
market structures similar to monopolistic competition include
restaurants, cereal, clothing, shoes, and service industries in large
cities.
Monopoly
A monopoly is a market structure in which a market or industry
is dominated by a single supplier of a particular good or service.
Because monopolies have no competition they tend to sell goods and
services at a higher price and produce below the socially optimal output
level. However, not all monopolies are a bad thing, especially in
industries where multiple firms would result in more costs than benefits
(i.e. natural monopolies).
- Natural monopoly: A monopoly in an industry where one producer can produce output at a lower cost than many small producers.
Oligopoly
An oligopoly is a market structure in which a market or industry is dominated by a small number of firms (oligopolists). Oligopolies can create the incentive for firms to engage in collusion and form cartels that reduce competition leading to higher prices for consumers and less overall market output. Alternatively, oligopolies can be fiercely competitive and engage in flamboyant advertising campaigns.
- Duopoly: A special case of an oligopoly, with only two firms. Game theory can elucidate behavior in duopolies and oligopolies.
Monopsony
A monopsony is a market where there is only one buyer and many sellers.
Oligopsony
An oligopsony is a market where there are a few buyers and many sellers.
Game theory
Game theory is a major method used in mathematical economics and business for modeling competing behaviors of interacting agents.
The term "game" here implies the study of any strategic interaction
between people. Applications include a wide array of economic phenomena
and approaches, such as auctions, bargaining, mergers & acquisitions pricing, fair division, duopolies, oligopolies, social network formation, agent-based computational economics, general equilibrium, mechanism design, and voting systems, and across such broad areas as experimental economics, behavioral economics, information economics, industrial organization, and political economy.
Labor economics
Labor economics seeks to understand the functioning and dynamics of the markets for wage labor. Labor markets
function through the interaction of workers and employers. Labor
economics looks at the suppliers of labor services (workers), the
demands of labor services (employers), and attempts to understand the
resulting pattern of wages, employment, and income. In economics, labor is a measure of the work done by human beings. It is conventionally contrasted with such other factors of production as land and capital. There are theories which have developed a concept called human capital
(referring to the skills that workers possess, not necessarily their
actual work), although there are also counter posing macro-economic
system theories that think human capital is a contradiction in terms.
Welfare economics
Welfare economics is a branch of economics that uses microeconomics techniques to evaluate well-being from allocation of productive factors as to desirability and economic efficiency within an economy, often relative to competitive general equilibrium. It analyzes social welfare, however measured,
in terms of economic activities of the individuals that compose the
theoretical society considered. Accordingly, individuals, with
associated economic activities, are the basic units
for aggregating to social welfare, whether of a group, a community, or a
society, and there is no "social welfare" apart from the "welfare"
associated with its individual units.
Economics of information
Information economics or the economics of information is a branch of microeconomic theory that studies how information and information systems affect an economy
and economic decisions. Information has special characteristics. It
is easy to create but hard to trust. It is easy to spread but hard to
control. It influences many decisions. These special characteristics
(as compared with other types of goods) complicate many standard
economic theories.
Applied
Applied microeconomics includes a range of specialized areas of study, many of which draw on methods from other fields. Industrial organization examines topics such as the entry and exit of firms, innovation, and the role of trademarks. Labor economics examines wages, employment, and labor market dynamics. Financial economics
examines topics such as the structure of optimal portfolios, the rate
of return to capital, econometric analysis of security returns, and
corporate financial behavior. Public economics examines the design of government tax and expenditure policies and economic effects of these policies (e.g., social insurance programs). Political economy examines the role of political institutions in determining policy outcomes. Health economics
examines the organization of health care systems, including the role of
the health care workforce and health insurance programs. Education economics
examines the organization of education provision and its implication
for efficiency and equity, including the effects of education on
productivity. Urban economics,
which examines the challenges faced by cities, such as sprawl, air and
water pollution, traffic congestion, and poverty, draws on the fields of
urban geography and sociology. Law and economics applies microeconomic principles to the selection and enforcement of competing legal regimes and their relative efficiencies. Economic history
examines the evolution of the economy and economic institutions, using
methods and techniques from the fields of economics, history, geography,
sociology, psychology, and political science.