The gravity model of international trade in international economics is a model that, in its traditional form, predicts bilateral trade flows
based on the economic sizes and distance between two units. Research
shows that there is "overwhelming evidence that trade tends to fall with
distance."
The model was first introduced in economics world by Walter Isard in 1954. The basic model for trade between two countries (i and j) takes the form of
The model has also been applied to other bilateral flow data (also 'dyadic' data) such as migration, traffic, remittances and foreign direct investment.
The model was first introduced in economics world by Walter Isard in 1954. The basic model for trade between two countries (i and j) takes the form of
The model has also been applied to other bilateral flow data (also 'dyadic' data) such as migration, traffic, remittances and foreign direct investment.
Theoretical justifications and research
The
model has been an empirical success in that it accurately predicts
trade flows between countries for many goods and services, but for a
long time some scholars believed that there was no theoretical
justification for the gravity equation. However, a gravity relationship can arise in almost any trade model that includes trade costs that increase with distance.
The gravity model estimates the pattern of international trade.
While the model’s basic form consists of factors that have more to do
with geography and spatiality, the gravity model has been used to test
hypotheses rooted in purer economic theories of trade as well. One such
theory predicts that trade will be based on relative factor abundances.
One of the common relative factor abundance models is the Heckscher–Ohlin model.
Those countries with a relative abundance of one factor would be
expected to produce goods that require a relatively large amount of that
factor in their production. While a generally accepted theory of trade,
many economists in the Chicago School believed that the Heckscher–Ohlin
model alone was sufficient to describe all trade, while Bertil Ohlin
himself argued that in fact the world is more complicated.
Investigations into real-world trading patterns have produced a number
of results that do not match the expectations of comparative advantage
theories. Notably, a study by Wassily Leontief found that the United States, the most capital-endowed country in the world, actually exports
more in labor-intensive industries. Comparative advantage in factor
endowments would suggest the opposite would occur. Other theories of
trade and explanations for this relationship were proposed in order to
explain the discrepancy between Leontief’s empirical findings and
economic theory. The problem has become known as the Leontief paradox.
An alternative theory, first proposed by Staffan Linder,
predicts that patterns of trade will be determined by the aggregated
preferences for goods within countries. Those countries with similar
preferences would be expected to develop similar industries. With
continued similar demand, these countries would continue to trade back
and forth in differentiated but similar goods since both demand and produce similar products. For instance, both Germany and the United States
are industrialized countries with a high preference for automobiles.
Both countries have automobile industries, and both trade cars. The
empirical validity of the Linder hypothesis
is somewhat unclear. Several studies have found a significant impact of
the Linder effect, but others have had weaker results. Studies that do
not support Linder have only counted countries that actually trade; they
do not input zero values for the dyads where trade could happen but
does not. This has been cited as a possible explanation for their
findings. Also, Linder never presented a formal model for his theory, so
different studies have tested his hypothesis in different ways.
Elhanan Helpman and Paul Krugman
asserted that the theory behind comparative advantage does not predict
the relationships in the gravity model. Using the gravity model,
countries with similar levels of income have been shown to trade more.
Helpman and Krugman see this as evidence that these countries are
trading in differentiated goods because of their similarities. This
casts some doubt about the impact Heckscher–Ohlin has on the real world.
Jeffrey Frankel
sees the Helpman–Krugman setup here as distinct from Linder’s proposal.
However, he does say Helpman–Krugman is different from the usual
interpretation of Linder, but, since Linder made no clear model, the
association between the two should not be completely discounted. Alan Deardorff
adds the possibility, that, while not immediately apparent, the basic
gravity model can be derived from Heckscher–Ohlin as well as the Linder
and Helpman–Krugman hypotheses. Deardorff concludes that, considering
how many models can be tied to the gravity model equation, it is not
useful for evaluating the empirical validity of theories.
Bridging economic theory with empirical tests, James Anderson and Jeffrey Bergstrand
develop econometric models, grounded in the theories of differentiated
goods, which measure the gains from trade liberalizations and the
magnitude of the border barriers on trade (see Home bias in trade puzzle).
A recent synthesis of empirical research using the gravity equations,
however, shows that the effect of border barriers on trade is relatively
modest.
Adding to the problem of bridging economic theory with empirical results, some economists have pointed to the possibility of intra-industry trade not as the result of differentiated goods, but because of “reciprocal dumping.”
In these models, the countries involved are said to have imperfect
competition and segmented markets in homogeneous goods, which leads to
intra-industry trade as firms in imperfect competition seek to expand
their markets to other countries and trade goods that are not
differentiated yet for which they do not have a comparative advantage,
since there is no specialization. This model of trade is consistent with
the gravity model as it would predict that trade depends on country
size.
The reciprocal dumping model has held up to some empirical
testing, suggesting that the specialization and differentiated goods
models for the gravity equation might not fully explain the gravity
equation. Feenstra, Markusen, and Rose (2001) provided evidence for
reciprocal dumping by assessing the home market effect
in separate gravity equations for differentiated and homogeneous goods.
The home market effect showed a relationship in the gravity estimation
for differentiated goods, but showed the inverse relationship for
homogeneous goods. The authors show that this result matches the
theoretical predictions of reciprocal dumping playing a role in
homogeneous markets.
Past research using the gravity model has also sought to evaluate
the impact of various variables in addition to the basic gravity
equation. Among these, price level and exchange rate variables have been
shown to have a relationship in the gravity model that accounts for a
significant amount of the variance not explained by the basic gravity
equation. According to empirical results on price level, the effect of
price level varies according to the relationship being examined. For
instance, if exports are being examined, a relatively high price level
on the part of the importer would be expected to increase trade with
that country. A non-linear system of equations are used by Anderson and
van Wincoop (2003) to account for the endogenous change in these price
terms from trade liberalization.
A more simple method is to use a first order log-linearization of this
system of equations (Baier and Bergstrand (2009)), or
exporter-country-year and importer-country-year dummy variables. For counterfactual analysis, however, one would still need to account for the change in world prices.
Econometric estimation of gravity equations
Since the gravity model for trade does not hold exactly, in econometric applications it is customary to specify
where represents volume of trade from country to country , and typically represent the GDPs for countries and , denotes the distance between the two countries, and represents an error term with expectation equal to 1.
The traditional approach to estimating this equation consists in
taking logs of both sides, leading to a log-log model of the form (note:
constant G becomes part of ):
However, this approach has two major problems. First, it obviously cannot be used when there are observations for which is equal to zero. Second, Santos Silva and Tenreyro (2006) argued that estimating the log-linearized equation by least squares
(OLS) can lead to significant biases. As an alternative, these authors
have suggested that the model should be estimated in its multiplicative
form, i.e.,
using a Poisson pseudo-maximum likelihood (PPML) estimator usually
used for count data. This is despite the fact that simpler methods, such
as taking simple averages of trade shares of countries with and without
former colonial ties suggest that countries with former colonial ties
continue to trade more. Santos Silva and Tenreyro (2006) did not explain
where their result came from and even failed to realize their results
were highly anomalous. Martin and Pham (2008) argued that using PPML on
gravity severely biases estimates when zero trade flows are frequent.
However, their results were challenged by Santos Silva and Tenreyro
(2011), who argued that the simulation results of Martin and Pham (2008)
are based on misspecified models and showed that the PPML estimator
performs well even when the proportions of zeros is very large.
In applied work, the model is often extended by including
variables to account for language relationships, tariffs, contiguity,
access to sea, colonial history, and exchange rate regimes. Yet the
estimation of structural gravity, based on Anderson and van Wincoop
(2003), requires the inclusion of importer and exporter fixed effects,
thus limiting the gravity analysis to bilateral trade costs (Baldwin and
Taglioni 2007).