An electoral system or voting system is a set of rules
that determine how elections and referendums are conducted and how their
results are determined. Political electoral systems are organized by
governments, while non-political elections may take place in business, non-profit organisations and informal organisations. These rules govern all aspects of the voting process: when elections occur, who is allowed to vote, who can stand as a candidate, how ballots are marked and cast, how the ballots are counted (electoral method), limits on campaign spending,
and other factors that can affect the outcome. Political electoral
systems are defined by constitutions and electoral laws, are typically
conducted by election commissions, and can use multiple types of elections for different offices.
Some electoral systems elect a single winner to a unique
position, such as prime minister, president or governor, while others
elect multiple winners, such as members of parliament or boards of
directors. There are many variations in electoral systems, but the most
common systems are first-past-the-post voting, the two-round (runoff) system, proportional representation and ranked voting. Some electoral systems, such as mixed systems, attempt to combine the benefits of non-proportional and proportional systems.
The study of formally defined electoral methods is called social choice theory or voting theory, and this study can take place within the field of political science, economics, or mathematics, and specifically within the subfields of game theory and mechanism design. Impossibility proofs such as Arrow's impossibility theorem demonstrate that when voters have three or more alternatives, it is not possible to design a ranked voting
electoral system that reflects the preferences of individuals in a
global preference of the community, present in countries with proportional representation and plurality voting.
Types of electoral systems
Plurality systems
Plurality voting
is a system in which the candidate(s) with the highest number of votes
wins, with no requirement to get a majority of votes. In cases where
there is a single position to be filled, it is known as first-past-the-post;
this is the second most common electoral system for national
legislatures, with 58 countries using it to elect their legislatures,
the vast majority of which are current or former British or American
colonies or territories. It is also the second most common system used
for presidential elections, being used in 19 countries.
In cases where there are multiple positions to be filled, most
commonly in cases of multi-member constituencies, plurality voting is
referred to as block voting or plurality-at-large.
This takes two main forms: in one form voters have as many votes as
there are seats and can vote for any candidate, regardless of party –
this is used in eight countries. There are variations on this system such as limited voting, where voters are given fewer votes than there are seats to be filled (Gibraltar is the only territory where this system is in use) and single non-transferable vote
(SNTV), in which voters can vote for only one candidate in a
multi-member constituency, with the candidates receiving the most votes
declared the winners; this system is used in Afghanistan, Kuwait, the Pitcairn Islands and Vanuatu.
In the other main form of block voting, also known as party block
voting, voters can only vote for the multiple candidates of a single
party. This is used in five countries as part of mixed systems.
The Dowdall system, a multi-member constituency variation on the Borda count, is used in Nauru
for parliamentary elections and sees voters rank the candidates
depending on how many seats there are in their constituency. First
preference votes are counted as whole numbers; the second preference
votes divided by two, third preferences by three; this continues to the
lowest possible ranking. The totals achieved by each candidate determine the winners.
Majoritarian systems
Majoritarian
voting is a system in which candidates have to receive a majority of
the votes to be elected, although in some cases only a plurality is
required in the last round of counting if no candidate can achieve a
majority. There are two main forms of majoritarian systems, one using a
single round of ranked voting and the other using two or more rounds. Both are primarily used for single-member constituencies.
Majoritarian voting can take place in a single round using instant-runoff voting (IRV), whereby voters rank candidates in order of preference; this system is used for parliamentary elections in Australia and Papua New Guinea.
If no candidate receives a majority of the vote in the first round, the
second preferences of the lowest-ranked candidate are then added to the
totals. This is repeated until a candidate achieves over 50% of the
number of valid votes. If not all voters use all their preference votes,
then the count may continue until two candidates remain, at which point
the winner is the one with the most votes. A modified form of IRV is
the contingent vote
where voters do not rank all candidates, but have a limited number of
preference votes. If no candidate has a majority in the first round, all
candidates are excluded except the top two, with the highest remaining
preference votes from the votes for the excluded candidates then added
to the totals to determine the winner. This system is used in Sri Lankan presidential elections, with voters allowed to give three preferences.
The other main form of majoritarian system is the two-round system,
which is the most common system used for presidential elections around
the world, being used in 88 countries. It is also used in 20 countries
for electing the legislature.
If no candidate achieves a majority of votes in the first round of
voting, a second round is held to determine the winner. In most cases
the second round is limited to the top two candidates from the first
round, although in some elections more than two candidates may choose to
contest the second round; in these cases the second round is decided by
plurality voting. Some countries use a modified form of the two-round
system, such as Ecuador
where a candidate in the presidential election is declared the winner
if they receive 40% of the vote and are 10% ahead of their nearest
rival, or Argentina (45% plus 10% ahead), where the system is known as ballotage.
An exhaustive ballot
is not limited to two rounds, but sees the last-placed candidate
eliminated in each round of voting. Due to the potentially large number
of rounds, this system is not used in any major popular elections, but
is used to elect the Speakers of parliament in several countries and
members of the Swiss Federal Council.
In some formats there may be multiple rounds held without any
candidates being eliminated until a candidate achieves a majority, a
system used in the United States Electoral College.
Proportional systems
Proportional representation
is the most widely used electoral system for national legislatures,
with the parliaments of over eighty countries elected by various forms
of the system.
Party-list proportional representation
is the single most common electoral system and is used by 80 countries,
and involves voters voting for a list of candidates proposed by a
party. In closed list systems voters do not have any influence over the candidates put forward by the party, but in open list
systems voters are able to both vote for the party list and influence
the order in which candidates will be assigned seats. In some countries,
notably Israel and the Netherlands,
elections are carried out using 'pure' proportional representation,
with the votes tallied on a national level before assigning seats to
parties. However, in most cases several multi-member constituencies are
used rather than a single nationwide constituency, giving an element of
geographical representation; but this can result in the distribution of
seats not reflecting the national vote totals. As a result, some
countries have leveling seats to award to parties whose seat totals are lower than their proportion of the national vote.
In addition to the electoral threshold
(the minimum percentage of the vote that a party must obtain to win
seats), there are several different ways to allocate seats in
proportional systems. There are two main types of system: highest average and largest remainder.
Highest average systems involve dividing the votes received by each
party by a series of divisors, producing figures that determine seat
allocation; for example the D'Hondt method (of which there are variants including Hagenbach-Bischoff) and the Webster/Sainte-Laguë method.
Under largest remainder systems, parties' vote shares are divided by
the quota (obtained by dividing the total number of votes by the number
of seats available). This usually leaves some seats unallocated, which
are awarded to parties based on the largest fractions of seats that they
have remaining. Examples of largest remainder systems include the Hare quota, Droop quota, the Imperiali quota and the Hagenbach-Bischoff quota.
Single transferable vote (STV) is another form of proportional representation; in STV, voters rank candidates in a multi-member constituency rather than voting for a party list; it is used in Malta and the Republic of Ireland. To be elected, candidates must pass a quota (the Droop quota
being the most common). Candidates that pass the quota on the first
count are elected. Votes are then reallocated from the least successful
candidates, as well as surplus votes from successful candidates, until
all seats have been filled by candidates who have passed the quota.
Mixed systems
In several countries, mixed systems are used to elect the legislature. These include parallel voting and mixed-member proportional representation.
In parallel voting systems, which are used in 20 countries,
there are two methods by which members of a legislature are elected;
part of the membership is elected by a plurality or majority vote in
single-member constituencies and the other part by proportional
representation. The results of the constituency vote have no effect on
the outcome of the proportional vote.
Mixed-member proportional representation, in use in eight
countries, also sees the membership of the legislature elected by
constituency and proportional methods, but in this case the results of
the proportional vote are adjusted to balance the seats won in the
constituency vote in order to ensure that parties have a number of seats
proportional to their vote share. This may result in overhang seats,
where parties win more seats in the constituency system than they would
be entitled to based on their vote share. Variations of this include
the Additional Member System and Alternative Vote Plus,
in which voters cast votes for both single-member constituencies and
multi-member constituencies; the allocation of seats in the multi-member
constituencies is adjusted to achieve an overall seat total
proportional to parties' vote share by taking into account the number of
seats won by parties in the single-member constituencies. A form of
mixed-member proportional representation, Scorporo, was used in Italy from 1993 until 2006.
Additional features
Some electoral systems feature a majority bonus system
to either ensure one party or coalition gains a majority in the
legislature, or to give the party receiving the most votes a clear
advantage in terms of the number of seats. In Greece the party receiving the most votes is given an additional 50 seats,[6] San Marino
has a modified two-round system, which sees a second round of voting
featuring the top two parties or coalitions if there is no majority in
the first round. The winner of the second round is guaranteed 35 seats
in the 60-seat Grand and General Council.
In Uruguay, the President and members of the General Assembly
are elected by on a single ballot, known as the double simultaneous
vote. Voters cast a single vote, voting for the presidential, Senatorial
and Chamber of Deputies candidates of that party. This system was also
previously used in Bolivia and the Dominican Republic.
Primary elections
Primary elections
are a feature of some electoral systems, either as a formal part of the
electoral system or informally by choice of individual political
parties as a method of selecting candidates, as is the case in Italy. Primary elections limit the risk of vote splitting by ensuring a single party candidate. In Argentina
they are a formal part of the electoral system and take place two
months before the main elections; any party receiving less than 1.5% of
the vote is not permitted to contest the main elections. In the United
States, there are both partisan and non-partisan primary elections.
Indirect elections
Some
elections feature an indirect electoral system, whereby there is either
no popular vote, or the popular vote is only one stage of the election;
in these systems the final vote is usually taken by an electoral college. In several countries, such as Mauritius or Trinidad and Tobago, the post of President is elected by the legislature. In others like India, the vote is taken by an electoral college consisting of the national legislature and state legislatures. In the United States, the president is indirectly elected using a two-stage process; a popular vote in each state elects members to the electoral college
that in turn elects the President. This can result in a situation where
a candidate who receives the most votes nationwide does not win the
electoral college vote, as most recently happened in 2000 and 2016.
Systems used outside politics
In
addition to the various electoral systems in use in the political
sphere, there are numerous others, some of which are proposals and some
of which have been adopted for usage in business (such as electing
corporate board members) or for organisations but not for public
elections.
Ranked systems include Bucklin voting, the various Condorcet methods (Copeland's, Dodgson's, Kemeny-Young, Maximal lotteries, Minimax, Nanson's, Ranked pairs, Schulze), the Coombs' method and positional voting. There are also several variants of single transferable vote, including CPO-STV, Schulze STV and the Wright system. Dual-member proportional representation
is a proposed system with two candidates elected in each constituency,
one with the most votes and one to ensure proportionality of the
combined results. Biproportional apportionment
is a system whereby the total number of votes is used to calculate the
number of seats each party is due, followed by a calculation of the
constituencies in which the seats should be awarded in order to achieve
the total due to them.
Cardinal electoral systems allow voters to score candidates independently. The complexity ranges from approval voting where voters simply state whether they approve of a candidate or not to range voting, where a candidate is scored from a set range of numbers. Other cardinal systems include proportional approval voting, sequential proportional approval voting, satisfaction approval voting, majority judgment and the Janeček Method where voters can cast positive and negative votes.
Historically, weighted voting
systems were used in some countries. These allocated a greater weight
to the votes of some voters than others, either indirectly by allocating
more seats to certain groups (such as the Prussian three-class franchise), or by weighting the results of the vote. The latter system was used in colonial Rhodesia for the 1962 and 1965 elections.
The elections featured two voter rolls (the 'A' roll being largely
European and the 'B' roll largely African); the seats of the House
Assembly were divided into 50 constituency seats and 15 district seats.
Although all voters could vote for both types of seats, 'A' roll votes
were given greater weight for the constituency seats and 'B' roll votes
greater weight for the district seats. Weighted systems are still used
in corporate elections, with votes weighted to reflect stock ownership.
Rules and regulations
In
addition to the specific method of electing candidates, electoral
systems are also characterised by their wider rules and regulations,
which are usually set out in a country's constitution or electoral law. Participatory rules determine candidate nomination and voter registration, in addition to the location of polling places and the availability of online voting, postal voting, and absentee voting. Other regulations include the selection of voting devices such as paper ballots, machine voting or open ballot systems, and consequently the type of vote counting systems, verification and auditing used.
Electoral rules place limits on suffrage and candidacy. Most countries's electorates are characterised by universal suffrage, but there are differences on the age at which people are allowed to vote,
with the youngest being 16 and the oldest 21 (although voters must be
25 to vote in Senate elections in Italy). People may be disenfranchised
for a range of reasons, such as being a serving prisoner, being declared
bankrupt, having committed certain crimes or being a serving member of
the armed forces. Similar limits are placed on candidacy (also known as
passive suffrage), and in many cases the age limit for candidates is
higher than the voting age. A total of 21 countries have compulsory voting, although in some there is an upper age limit on enforcement of the law. Many countries also have the none of the above option on their ballot papers.
In systems that use constituencies, apportionment
or districting defines the area covered by each constituency. Where
constituency boundaries are drawn has a strong influence on the likely
outcome of elections in the constituency due to the geographic
distribution of voters. Political parties may seek to gain an advantage
during redistricting by ensuring their voter base has a majority in as many constituencies as possible, a process known as gerrymandering. Historically rotten and pocket boroughs, constituencies with unusually small populations, were used by wealthy families to gain parliamentary representation.
Some countries have minimum turnout requirements for elections to
be valid. In Serbia this rule caused multiple re-runs of presidential
elections, with the 1997 election re-run once and the 2002 elections
re-run three times due insufficient turnout in the first, second and third attempts to run the election. The turnout requirement was scrapped prior to the fourth vote in 2004. Similar problems in Belarus led to the 1995 parliamentary elections going to a fourth round of voting before enough parliamentarians were elected to make a quorum.
Reserved seats
are used in many countries to ensure representation for ethnic
minorities, women, young people or the disabled. These seats are
separate from general seats, and may be elected separately (such as in
Morocco where a separate ballot is used to elect the 60 seats reserved
for women and 30 seats reserved for young people in the House of
Representatives), or be allocated to parties based on the results of the
election; in Jordan
the reserved seats for women are given to the female candidates who
failed to win constituency seats but with the highest number of votes,
whilst in Kenya
the Senate seats reserved for women, young people and the disabled are
allocated to parties based on how many seats they won in the general
vote. Some countries achieve minority representation by other means,
including requirements for a certain proportion of candidates to be
women, or by exempting minority parties from the electoral threshold, as
is done in Poland, Romania and Serbia.
History
Pre-democratic
In ancient Greece and Italy, the institution of suffrage already existed in a rudimentary form at the outset of the historical period. In the early monarchies
it was customary for the king to invite pronouncements of his people on
matters in which it was prudent to secure its assent beforehand. In
these assemblies the people recorded their opinion by clamouring (a
method which survived in Sparta as late as the 4th century BCE), or by the clashing of spears on shields.
Early democracy
Voting has been used as a feature of democracy since the 6th century BC, when democracy was introduced by the Athenian democracy.
However, in Athenian democracy, voting was seen as the least democratic
among methods used for selecting public officials, and was little used,
because elections were believed to inherently favor the wealthy and
well-known over average citizens. Viewed as more democratic were
assemblies open to all citizens, and selection by lot (known as sortition), as well as rotation of office.
Generally, the taking of votes was effected in the form of a
poll. The practice of the Athenians, which is shown by inscriptions to
have been widely followed in the other states of Greece, was to hold a
show of hands, except on questions affecting the status of individuals:
these latter, which included all lawsuits and proposals of ostracism,
in which voters chose the citizen they most wanted to exile for ten
years, were determined by secret ballot (one of the earliest recorded
elections in Athens was a plurality vote that it was undesirable to win, namely an ostracism vote). At Rome the method which prevailed up to the 2nd century BCE was that of division (discessio).
But the system became subject to intimidation and corruption. Hence a
series of laws enacted between 139 and 107 BCE prescribed the use of the
ballot (tabella), a slip
of wood coated with wax, for all business done in the assemblies of the
people.
For the purpose of carrying resolutions a simple majority of votes was
deemed sufficient. As a general rule equal value was made to attach to
each vote; but in the popular assemblies at Rome a system of voting by
groups was in force until the middle of the 3rd century BCE by which the
richer classes secured a decisive preponderance.
Most elections in the early history of democracy were held using plurality voting or some variant, but as an exception, the state of Venice in the 13th century adopted approval voting to elect their Great Council.
The Venetians' method for electing the Doge
was a particularly convoluted process, consisting of five rounds of
drawing lots (sortition) and five rounds of approval voting. By drawing
lots, a body of 30 electors was chosen, which was further reduced to
nine electors by drawing lots again. An electoral college
of nine members elected 40 people by approval voting; those 40 were
reduced to form a second electoral college of 12 members by drawing lots
again. The second electoral college elected 25 people by approval
voting, which were reduced to form a third electoral college of nine
members by drawing lots. The third electoral college elected 45 people,
which were reduced to form a fourth electoral college of 11 by drawing
lots. They in turn elected a final electoral body of 41 members, who
ultimately elected the Doge. Despite its complexity, the method had
certain desirable properties such as being hard to game and ensuring
that the winner reflected the opinions of both majority and minority
factions. This process, with slight modifications, was central to the politics of the Republic of Venice throughout its remarkable lifespan of over 500 years, from 1268 to 1797.
Development of new systems
Jean-Charles de Borda proposed the Borda count in 1770 as a method for electing members to the French Academy of Sciences. His method was opposed by the Marquis de Condorcet,
who proposed instead the method of pairwise comparison that he had
devised. Implementations of this method are known as Condorcet methods.
He also wrote about the Condorcet paradox, which he called the intransitivity of majority preferences. However, recent research has shown that the philosopher Ramon Llull
devised both the Borda count and a pairwise method that satisfied the
Condorcet criterion in the 13th century. The manuscripts in which he
described these methods had been lost to history until they were
rediscovered in 2001.
Later in the 18th century, apportionment methods came to prominence due to the United States Constitution, which mandated that seats in the United States House of Representatives had to be allocated among the states proportionally to their population, but did not specify how to do so. A variety of methods were proposed by statesmen such as Alexander Hamilton, Thomas Jefferson, and Daniel Webster.
Some of the apportionment methods devised in the United States were in a
sense rediscovered in Europe in the 19th century, as seat allocation
methods for the newly proposed method of party-list proportional
representation. The result is that many apportionment methods have two
names; Jefferson's method is equivalent to the D'Hondt method, as is Webster's method to the Sainte-Laguë method, while Hamilton's method is identical to the Hare largest remainder method.
The single transferable vote (STV) method was devised by Carl Andræ in Denmark in 1855 and in the United Kingdom by Thomas Hare in 1857. STV elections were first held in Denmark in 1856, and in Tasmania in 1896 after its use was promoted by Andrew Inglis Clark. Party-list proportional representation began to be used to elect European legislatures in the early 20th century, with Belgium the first to implement it for its 1900 general elections.
Since then, proportional and semi-proportional methods have come to be
used in almost all democratic countries, with most exceptions being
former British colonies.
Single-winner revival
Perhaps
influenced by the rapid development of multiple-winner electoral
systems, theorists began to publish new findings about single-winner
methods in the late 19th century. This began around 1870, when William Robert Ware proposed applying STV to single-winner elections, yielding instant-runoff voting (IRV). Soon, mathematicians began to revisit Condorcet's ideas and invent new methods for Condorcet completion; Edward J. Nanson combined the newly described instant runoff voting with the Borda count to yield a new Condorcet method called Nanson's method. Charles Dodgson, better known as Lewis Carroll, proposed the straightforward Condorcet method known as Dodgson's method.
He also proposed a proportional representation system based on
multi-member districts, quotas as minimum requirements to take seats,
and votes transferable by candidates through proxy voting.
Ranked voting electoral systems eventually gathered enough support to be adopted for use in government elections. In Australia, IRV was first adopted in 1893, and continues to be used along with STV today. In the United States in the early-20th-century progressive era, some municipalities began to use Bucklin voting, although this is no longer used in any government elections, and has even been declared unconstitutional in Minnesota.
Recent developments
The use of game theory to analyze electoral systems led to discoveries about the effects of certain methods. Earlier developments such as Arrow's impossibility theorem had already shown the issues with Ranked voting systems. Research led Steven Brams and Peter Fishburn to formally define and promote the use of approval voting in 1977.
Political scientists of the 20th century published many studies on the
effects that the electoral systems have on voters' choices and political
parties, and on political stability. A few scholars also studied which effects caused a nation to switch to a particular electoral system. One prominent current voting theorist is Nicolaus Tideman, who formalized concepts such as strategic nomination and the spoiler effect in the independence of clones criterion. Tideman also devised the ranked pairs method, a Condorcet method that is not susceptible to clones.
The study of electoral systems influenced a new push for electoral reform beginning around the 1990s, when proposals were made to replace plurality voting in governmental elections with other methods. New Zealand adopted mixed-member proportional representation for the 1993 general elections and STV for some local elections in 2004. After plurality voting was a key factor in the contested results of the 2000 presidential elections in the United States, various municipalities in the United States began to adopt Instant-runoff voting,
although some of them subsequently returned to their prior method.
However, attempts at introducing more proportional systems were not
always successful; in Canada there were two referendums in British
Columbia in 2005 and 2009 on adopting an STV method, both of which failed. In the United Kingdom, a 2011 referendum on adopting IRV saw the proposal rejected.
In other countries there were calls for the restoration of
plurality or majoritarian systems or their establishment where they have
never been used; a referendum
was held in Ecuador in 1994 on the adoption the two round system, but
the idea was rejected. In Romania a proposal to switch to a two-round
system for parliamentary elections failed only because voter turnout in the referendum was too low. Attempts to reintroduce single-member constituencies in Poland (2015) and two-round system in Bulgaria (2016) via referendums both also failed due to low turnout.
Comparison of electoral systems
Electoral systems can be compared by different means. Attitudes
towards systems are highly influenced by the systems' impact on groups
that one supports or opposes, which can make the objective comparison of
voting systems difficult. There are several ways to address this
problem:
One approach is to define criteria mathematically, such that any
electoral system either passes or fails. This gives perfectly objective
results, but their practical relevance is still arguable.
Another approach is to define ideal criteria that no electoral
system passes perfectly, and then see how often or how close to passing
various methods are over a large sample of simulated elections. This
gives results which are practically relevant, but the method of
generating the sample of simulated elections can still be arguably
biased.
A final approach is to create imprecisely defined criteria, and
then assign a neutral body to evaluate each method according to these
criteria. This approach can look at aspects of electoral systems which
the other two approaches miss, but both the definitions of these
criteria and the evaluations of the methods are still inevitably
subjective.
Arrow's and Gibbard's
theorems prove that no system using ranked voting or cardinal voting,
can meet all such criteria simultaneously. Instead of debating the
importance of different criteria, another method is to simulate many
elections with different electoral systems, and estimate the typical
overall happiness of the population with the results, their vulnerability to strategic voting, their likelihood of electing the candidate closest to the average voter, etc.