Sharecropping is when a landowner allows a tenant to use the land in return for a share of the crops produced on the land.
Sharecropping has a long history and there are a wide range of
different situations and types of agreements that have used a form of
the system. Some are governed by tradition, and others by law. Legal
contract systems such as the Italian mezzadria, the French métayage, the Spanish mediero, the Slavic połowcy,издoльщина or the Islamic system of muqasat, occur widely.
Overview
Sharecropping
has benefits and costs for both the owners and the tenant. Everyone
encourages the cropper to remain on the land, solving the harvest
rush problem. At the same time, since the cropper pays in shares of his
harvest, owners and croppers share the risks of harvests being large or
small and of prices being high or low. Because tenants benefit from
larger harvests, they have an incentive to work harder and invest in
better methods than in a slave plantation system. However, by dividing
the working force into many individual workers, large farms no longer
benefit from economies of scale. On the whole, sharecropping was not as economically efficient as the gang agriculture of slave plantations.
In the U.S., "tenant" farmers owned their own mules and
equipment, and "sharecroppers" did not, and thus sharecroppers were
poorer and of lower status.
Sharecropping occurred extensively in Scotland, Ireland and colonial Africa, and came into wide use in the Southern United States during the Reconstruction
era (1865–1877). The South had been devastated by war – planters had
ample land but little money for wages or taxes. At the same time, most
of the former slaves could provide labor but had no money or land – they
rejected the kind of gang labor that typified slavery. A solution was
the sharecropping system focused on cotton, which was the only crop that
could generate cash for the croppers, landowners, merchants and the tax
collector. Poor white farmers who previously had done little cotton farming needed cash as well and became sharecroppers.
Jeffery Paige made a distinction between centralized
sharecropping found on cotton plantations and the decentralized
sharecropping with other crops. The former is characterized by political
conservatism and long lasting tenure. Tenants are tied to the landlord
through the plantation store. Their work is heavily supervised as slave
plantations were. This form of tenure tends to be replaced by wage slavery
as markets penetrate. Decentralized sharecropping involves virtually no
role for the landlord: plots are scattered, peasants manage their own
labor and the landowners do not manufacture the crops. Leases are very
short which leads to peasant radicalism. This form of tenure becomes
more common when markets penetrate.
Use of the sharecropper system has also been identified in England (as the practice of "farming to halves"). It is still used in many rural poor areas of the world today, notably in Pakistan and India.
Although there is a perception that sharecropping was
exploitative, "evidence from around the world suggests that
sharecropping is often a way for differently endowed enterprises to pool
resources to mutual benefit, overcoming credit restraints and helping
to manage risk." According to Dr. Hunter, "a few acres to the cottage would make the labourers too independent."
It can have more than a passing similarity to serfdom or indenture,
particularly where associated with large debts at a plantation store
that effectively ties down the workers and their family to the land. It
has therefore been seen as an issue of land reform in contexts such as the Mexican Revolution.
However, Nyambara states that Eurocentric historiographical devices
such as 'feudalism' or 'slavery' often qualified by weak prefixes like
'semi-' or 'quasi-' are not helpful in understanding the antecedents and
functions of sharecropping in Africa.
Sharecropping agreements can, however, be made fairly, as a form of tenant farming or sharefarming that has a variable rental payment, paid in arrears. There are three different types of contracts.
- Workers can rent plots of land from the owner for a certain sum and keep the whole crop.
- Workers work on the land and earn a fixed wage from the land owner but keep some of the crop.
- No money changes hands but the worker and land owner each keep a share of the crop.
However, many outside factors make it efficient. One factor is slave
emancipation: sharecropping provided the freed slaves of the US, Brazil
and the late Roman Empire with land access. It is efficient also as a
way of escaping inflation, hence its rise in 16th-century France and
Italy.
It also gave sharecroppers a vested interest in the land,
incentivizing hard work and care. American plantation were, however,
wary of this interest, as they felt that would lead to African Americans
demanding rights of partnership. Many black laborers denied the
unilateral authority that landowners hoped to achieve, further
complicating relations between landowners and sharecroppers.
Landlords opt for sharecropping to avoid the administrative costs and shirking that occurs on plantations and haciendas. It is preferred to cash tenancy because cash tenants take all the risks, and any harvest failure will hurt them and not the landlord. Therefore, they tend to demand lower rents than sharecroppers.
The advantages of sharecropping in other situations include enabling access for women to arable land where ownership rights are vested only in men.
Disadvantages
The
practice was harmful to tenants with many cases of high interest rates,
unpredictable harvests, and unscrupulous landlords and merchants often
keeping tenant farm families severely indebted. The debt was often
compounded year on year leaving the cropper vulnerable to intimidation
and shortchanging. Nevertheless, it appeared to be inevitable, with no serious alternative unless the croppers left agriculture.
A new system of credit, the crop lien,
became closely associated with sharecropping. Under this system, a
planter or merchant extended a line of credit to the sharecropper while
taking the year's crop as collateral. The sharecropper could then draw
food and supplies all year long. When the crop was harvested, the
planter or merchants who held the lien sold the harvest for the
sharecropper and settled the debt.
Regions
Africa
In
settler colonies of colonial Africa, sharecropping was a feature of the
agricultural life. White farmers, who owned most of the land, were
frequently unable to work the whole of their farm for lack of capital.
They, therefore, had African farmers to work the excess on a
sharecropping basis. In South Africa the 1913 Natives' Land Act
outlawed the ownership of land by Africans in areas designated for
white ownership and effectively reduced the status of most sharecroppers
to tenant farmers
and then to farm laborers. In the 1960s, generous subsidies to white
farmers meant that most farmers could afford to work their entire farms,
and sharecropping faded out.
The arrangement has reappeared in other African countries in modern times, including Ghana and Zimbabwe.
United States
Sharecropping became widespread in the South as a response to economic upheaval caused by the end of slavery during and after Reconstruction.
Sharecropping was a way for poor farmers, both white and black, to
earn a living from land owned by someone else. The landowner provided
land, housing, tools and seed, and perhaps a mule, and a local merchant
provided food and supplies on credit. At harvest time, the sharecropper
received a share of the crop (from one-third to one-half, with the
landowner taking the rest). The cropper used his share to pay off his
debt to the merchant.
The system started with Black farmers when large plantations were
subdivided. By the 1880s, white farmers also became sharecroppers. The
system was distinct from that of the tenant farmer, who rented the land,
provided his own tools and mule, and received half the crop. Landowners
provided more supervision to sharecroppers, and less or none to tenant
farmers. Sharecropping in the United States probably originated in the
Natchez District, roughly centered in Adams County, Mississippi with its county seat, Natchez.
Sharecroppers worked a section of the plantation independently, usually growing cotton, tobacco, rice, sugar, and other cash crops, and receiving half of the parcel's output. Sharecroppers also often received their farming tools and all other goods from the landowner they were contracted with.
Landowners dictated decisions relating to the crop mix, and
sharecroppers were often in agreements to sell their portion of the crop
back to the landowner, thus being subjected to manipulated prices.
In addition to this, landowners, threatening to not renew the lease at
the end of the growing season, were able to apply pressure to their
tenants. Sharecropping often proved economically problematic, as the landowners held significant economic control.
Although the sharecropping system was primarily a post-Civil War development, it did exist in antebellum Mississippi, especially in the northeastern part of the state, an area with few slaves or plantations, and most likely existed in Tennessee.
Sharecropping, along with tenant farming, was a dominant form in the
cotton South from the 1870s to the 1950s, among both blacks and whites.
Following the Civil War
of the United States, the South lay in ruins. Plantations and other
lands throughout the South were seized by the federal government, and
thousands of former slaves, known as freedmen, found themselves free, yet without means to support their families. The situation was made more complex due to General William T. Sherman's Special Field Orders No. 15,
which in January 1865, announced he would temporarily grant newly freed
families 40 acres of land on the islands and coastal regions of Georgia. This policy was also referred to as Forty Acres and a Mule.
Many believed that this policy would be extended to all former slaves
and their families as repayment for their treatment at the end of the
war.
An alternative path was selected and enforced. In the summer of 1865, President Andrew Johnson, as one of the first acts of Reconstruction,
instead ordered all land under federal control be returned to the
owners from whom it had been seized. This meant that plantation and land
owners in the South regained their land but lacked a labor force. The
solution was sharecropping, which enabled the government to match labor
with demand and begin the process of economically rebuilding the nation
via labor contracts.
In Reconstruction-era United States, sharecropping was one of few options for penniless freedmen to support themselves and their families. Other solutions included the crop-lien system
(where the farmer was extended credit for seed and other supplies by
the merchant), a rent labor system (where the former slave rents his
land but keeps his entire crop), and the wage system (worker earns a
fixed wage, but keeps none of their crop). Sharecropping was by far the
most economically efficient, as it provided incentives for workers to
produce a bigger harvest. It was a stage beyond simple hired labor
because the sharecropper had an annual contract. During Reconstruction, the federal Freedmen's Bureau ordered the arrangements and wrote and enforced the contracts.
After the Civil War, plantation owners had to borrow money to
farm, at around 15 percent interest. The indebtedness of cotton planters
increased through the early 1940s, and the average plantation fell into
bankruptcy about every 20 years. It is against this backdrop that the
wealthiest owners maintained their concentrated ownership of the land.
Croppers were assigned a plot of land to work, and in exchange owed
the owner a share of the crop at the end of the season, usually one
half. The owner provided the tools and farm animals. Farmers who owned
their own mule and plow were at a higher stage, and were called tenant farmers: They paid the landowner less, usually only a third of each crop. In both cases, the farmer kept the produce of gardens.
The sharecropper purchased seed, tools, and fertilizer, as well
as food and clothing, on credit from a local merchant, or sometimes from
a plantation store. At harvest time, the cropper would harvest the
whole crop and sell it to the merchant who had extended credit.
Purchases and the landowner's share were deducted and the cropper kept
the difference—or added to his debt.
Though the arrangement protected sharecroppers from the negative
effects of a bad crop, many sharecroppers (both black and white)
remained quite poor. Arrangements typically left a third of the crop to
the sharecropper.
By the early 1930s, there were 5.5 million white tenants,
sharecroppers, and mixed cropping/laborers in the United States; and 3
million blacks. In Tennessee, whites made up two thirds or more of the sharecroppers. In Mississippi, by 1900, 36% of all white farmers were tenants or sharecroppers, while 85% of black farmers were.
In Georgia, fewer than 16,000 farms were operated by black owners in
1910, while, at the same time, African Americans managed 106,738 farms
as tenants.
Sharecropping continued to be a significant institution in Tennessee agriculture for more than 60 years after the Civil War, peaking in importance in the early 1930s, when sharecroppers operated approximately one-third of all farm units in the state.
The situation of landless farmers who challenged the system in
the rural South as late as 1941 has been described thus: "he is at once a
target subject of ridicule and vitriolic denunciation; he may even be
waylaid by hooded or unhooded leaders of the community, some of whom may
be public officials. If a white man persists in 'causing trouble', the night riders may pay him a visit, or the officials may haul him into court; if he is a Negro, a mob may hunt him down."
Sharecroppers formed unions in the 1930s, beginning in Tallapoosa
County, Alabama in 1931, and Arkansas in 1934. Membership in the Southern Tenant Farmers Union
included both blacks and poor whites. As leadership strengthened,
meetings became more successful, and protest became more vigorous,
landlords responded with a wave of terror.
Sharecroppers' strikes in Arkansas and the Missouri Bootheel, the
1939 Missouri Sharecroppers' Strike, were documented in the film Oh Freedom After While. The plight of a sharecropper was addressed in the song Sharecropper's Blues recorded by Charlie Barnet and His Orchestra with vocals by Kay Starr (Decca 24264) in 1944. It was rerecorded and released by Capitol with Starr being backed by the David Beckham Ork" (Capitol Americana 40051). Decca then reissued the Barnet/Star recording.
In the 1930s and 1940s, increasing mechanization virtually
brought the institution of sharecropping to an end in the United States. The sharecropping system in the U.S. increased during the Great Depression with the creation of tenant farmers following the failure of many small farms throughout the Dustbowl. Traditional sharecropping declined after mechanization
of farm work became economical in the mid-20th century. As a result,
many sharecroppers were forced off the farms, and migrated to cities to
work in factories, or become migrant workers in the Western United States during World War II.
Typically,
a sharecropping agreement would specify which party was expected to
cover certain expenses, like seed, fertilizer, weed control, irrigation
district assessments, and fuel. Sometimes the sharecropper covered those
costs, but they expected a larger share of the crop in return. The
agreement would also indicate whether the sharecropper would use his own
equipment to raise the crops, or use the landlord's equipment. The
agreement would also indicate whether the landlord would pick up his or
her share of the crop in the field or whether the sharecropper would
deliver it (and where it would be delivered.)
For example, a landowner may have a sharecropper farming an
irrigated hayfield. The sharecropper uses his own equipment, and covers
all the costs of fuel and fertilizer. The landowner pays the irrigation
district assessments and does the irrigating himself. The sharecropper
cuts and bales the hay, and delivers one-third of the baled hay to the
landlord's feedlot. The sharecropper might also leave the landlord's
share of the baled hay in the field, where the landlord would fetch it
when he wanted hay.
Another arrangement could have the sharecropper delivering the
landlord's share of the product to market, in which case the landlord
would get his share in the form of the sale proceeds. In that case, the
agreement should indicate the timing of the delivery to market, which
can have a significant effect on the ultimate price of some crops. The market timing
decision should probably be decided shortly before harvest, so that the
landlord has more complete information about the area's harvest, to
determine whether the crop will earn more money immediately after
harvest, or whether it should be stored until the price rises. Market
timing can entail storage costs and losses to spoilage for some crops as
well.
Farmers' cooperatives
Cooperative farming
exists in many forms throughout the world. Various arrangements can be
made through collective bargaining or purchasing to get the best deals
on seeds, supplies, and equipment. For example, members of a farmers'
cooperative who cannot afford heavy equipment of their own can lease
them for nominal fees from the cooperative. Farmers' cooperatives can
also allow groups of small farmers and dairymen to manage pricing and
prevent undercutting by competitors.
The theory of share tenancy was long dominated by Alfred Marshall's famous footnote in Book VI, Chapter X.14 of Principles where he illustrated the inefficiency of agricultural share-contracting. Steven N.S. Cheung (1969),
challenged this view, showing that with sufficient competition and in
the absence of transaction costs, share tenancy will be equivalent to
competitive labor markets and therefore efficient.
He also showed that in the presence of transaction costs,
share-contracting may be preferred to either wage contracts or rent
contracts—due to the mitigation of labor shirking and the provision of
risk sharing. Joseph Stiglitz (1974, 1988),
suggested that if share tenancy is only a labor contract, then it is
only pairwise-efficient and that land-to-the-tiller reform would improve
social efficiency by removing the necessity for labor contracts in the
first place.
Reid (1973), Murrel (1983), Roumasset (1995) and Allen and Lueck (2004) provided transaction cost
theories of share-contracting, wherein tenancy is more of a partnership
than a labor contract and both landlord and tenant provide multiple
inputs. It has also been argued that the sharecropping institution can
be explained by factors such as informational asymmetry (Hallagan, 1978; Allen, 1982; Muthoo, 1998), moral hazard (Reid, 1976; Eswaran and Kotwal, 1985; Ghatak and Pandey, 2000),
intertemporal discounting (Roy and Serfes, 2001), price fluctuations (Sen, 2011) or limited liability (Shetty, 1988; Basu, 1992; Sengupta, 1997; Ray and Singh, 2001).