Thomas Robert Malthus
| |
---|---|
Portrait by John Linnell
| |
Born | 13/14 February 1766 |
Died | 23 December 1834 (aged 68) |
Nationality | British |
Field | Demography, macroeconomics |
School or tradition | Classical economics |
Alma mater | Jesus College, Cambridge |
Influences | David Ricardo, Jean Charles Léonard de Sismondi |
Contributions | Malthusian growth model |
Thomas Robert Malthus FRS (/ˈmælθəs/; 13 February 1766 – 23 December 1834) was an English cleric and scholar, influential in the fields of political economy and demography. Malthus himself used only his middle name, Robert.
In his 1798 book An Essay on the Principle of Population, Malthus observed that an increase in a nation's food production improved the well-being of the populace, but the improvement was temporary because it led to population growth, which in turn restored the original per capita production level. In other words, mankind had a propensity to utilize abundance for population growth rather than for maintaining a high standard of living, a view that has become known as the "Malthusian trap" or the "Malthusian spectre". Populations had a tendency to grow until the lower class suffered hardship and want and greater susceptibility to famine and disease, a view that is sometimes referred to as a Malthusian catastrophe. Malthus wrote in opposition to the popular view in 18th-century Europe that saw society as improving and in principle as perfectible. He saw population growth as being inevitable whenever conditions improved, thereby precluding real progress towards a utopian society: "The power of population is indefinitely greater than the power in the earth to produce subsistence for man". As an Anglican cleric, Malthus saw this situation as divinely imposed to teach virtuous behavior. Malthus wrote:
That the increase of population is necessarily limited by the means of subsistence,Malthus criticized the Poor Laws for leading to inflation rather than improving the well-being of the poor. He supported taxes on grain imports (the Corn Laws), because food security was more important than maximizing wealth. His views became influential, and controversial, across economic, political, social and scientific thought. Pioneers of evolutionary biology read him, notably Charles Darwin and Alfred Russel Wallace. He remains a much-debated writer.
That population does invariably increase when the means of subsistence increase, and,
That the superior power of population is repressed by moral restraint, vice and misery.
Early life and education
The sixth child of Henrietta Catherine (Graham) and Daniel Malthus, Robert Malthus grew up in The Rookery, a country house in Westcott, near Dorking in Surrey.
Thomas was bullied from an early age because of his syndactyly, or
webbed feet. This sparked his controversial ideas about eugenics.
Petersen describes Daniel Malthus as "a gentleman of good family and
independent means... [and] a friend of David Hume and Jean-Jacques Rousseau". The young Malthus received his education at home in Bramcote, Nottinghamshire, and then at the Warrington Academy from 1782. Warrington was a dissenting academy, which closed in 1783; Malthus continued for a period to be tutored by Gilbert Wakefield who had taught him there.
Malthus entered Jesus College, Cambridge in 1784. There he took prizes in English declamation, Latin and Greek, and graduated with honors, Ninth Wrangler in mathematics. His tutor was William Frend. He took the MA degree in 1791, and was elected a Fellow of Jesus College two years later. In 1789, he took orders in the Church of England, and became a curate at Oakwood Chapel (also Okewood) in the parish of Wotton, Surrey.
Population growth
Malthus came to prominence for his 1798 essay on population growth. In it, he argued that population multiplies geometrically and food arithmetically;
therefore, whenever the food supply increases, population will rapidly
grow to eliminate the abundance. Between 1798 and 1826 he published six
editions of An Essay on the Principle of Population,
updating each edition to incorporate new material, to address
criticism, and to convey changes in his own perspectives on the subject.
He wrote the original text in reaction to the optimism of his father
and his father's associates (notably Rousseau) regarding the future
improvement of society. Malthus also constructed his case as a specific
response to writings of William Godwin (1756–1836) and of the Marquis de Condorcet (1743–1794).
The Essay gave rise to the Malthusian controversy during the next decades. The content saw an emphasis on the birth rate and marriage rates. The neo-Malthusian controversy, or related debates of many years later, has seen a similar central role assigned to the numbers of children born.
In 1799 Malthus made a European tour with William Otter, a close college friend, travelling part of the way with Edward Daniel Clarke
and John Marten Cripps, visiting Germany, Scandinavia and Russia.
Malthus used the trip to gather population data. Otter later wrote a Memoir of Malthus for the second (1836) edition of his Principles of Political Economy. During the Peace of Amiens of 1802 he traveled to France and Switzerland, in a party that included his relation and future wife Harriet. In 1803 he became rector of Walesby, Lincolnshire.
Academic
In 1805 Malthus became Professor of History and Political Economy at the East India Company College in Hertfordshire. His students affectionately referred to him as "Pop", "Population", or "web-toe" Malthus.
At the end of 1816 the proposed appointment of Graves Champney Haughton to the College was made a pretext by Randle Jackson and Joseph Hume
to launch an attempt to close it down. Malthus wrote a pamphlet
defending the College, which was reprieved by the East India Company in
1817. In 1818 Malthus became a Fellow of the Royal Society.
Malthus–Ricardo debate on political economy
During the 1820s there took place a setpiece intellectual discussion within the proponents of political economy, often called the "Malthus–Ricardo debate", after the leading figures of Malthus and David Ricardo, a theorist of free trade, both of whom had written books with the title Principles of Political Economy.
Under examination were the nature and methods of political economy
itself, while it was simultaneously under attack from others. The roots of the debate were in the previous decade. In The Nature of Rent (1815), Malthus had dealt with economic rent, a major concept in classical economics. Ricardo defined a theory of rent in his Principles of Political Economy and Taxation
(1817): he regarded rent as value in excess of real
production—something caused by ownership rather than by free trade. Rent
therefore represented a kind of negative money that landlords could
pull out of the production of the land, by means of its scarcity. Contrary to this concept, Malthus proposed rent to be a kind of economic surplus.
The debate developed over the economic concept of a general glut, and the possibility of failure of Say's Law. Malthus laid importance on economic development and the persistence of disequilibrium. The context was the post-war depression; Malthus had a supporter in William Blake, in denying that capital accumulation (saving) was always good in such circumstances, and John Stuart Mill attacked Blake on the fringes of the debate.
Ricardo corresponded with Malthus from 1817 and his Principles.
He was drawn into considering political economy in a less restricted
sense, which might be adapted to legislation and its multiple
objectives, by the thought of Malthus. In his own work Principles of Political Economy
(1820), and elsewhere, Malthus addressed the tension, amounting to
conflict, he saw between a narrow view of political economy, and the
broader moral and political plane. Leslie Stephen wrote:
If Malthus and Ricardo differed, it was a difference of men who accepted the same first principles. They both professed to interpret Adam Smith as the true prophet, and represented different shades of opinion rather than diverging sects.
After Ricardo's death in 1823, Malthus became isolated among the
younger British political economists, who tended to think he had lost
the debate.It
is now considered that the different purposes seen by Malthus and
Ricardo for political economy affected their technical discussion, and
contributed to the lack of compatible definitions. For example, Jean-Baptiste Say used a definition of production based on goods and services and so queried the restriction of Malthus to "goods" alone.
In terms of public policy, Malthus was a supporter of the protectionist Corn Laws from the end of the Napoleonic Wars. He emerged as the only economist of note to support duties on imported grain. He changed his mind after 1814. By encouraging domestic production, Malthus argued, the Corn Laws would guarantee British self-sufficiency in food.
Later life
Malthus was a founding member of the Political Economy Club in 1821; there John Cazenove tended to be his ally, against Ricardo and Mill. He was elected in the beginning of 1824 as one of the ten royal associates of the Royal Society of Literature. He was also one of the first fellows of the Statistical Society, founded in March 1834. In 1827 he gave evidence to a committee of the House of Commons on emigration.
In 1827, he published Definitions in Political Economy,
preceded by an inquiry into the rules which ought to guide political
economists in the definition and use of their terms; with remarks on the
deviation from these rules in their writings.
The first chapter put forth "Rules for the Definition and Application
of Terms in Political Economy". In chapter 10, the penultimate chapter,
he presented 60 numbered paragraphs putting forth terms and their
definitions that he proposed, following those rules, should be used in
discussing political economy. This collection of terms and definitions
is remarkable for two reasons: first, Malthus was the first economist to
explicitly organize, define, and publish his terms as a coherent
glossary of defined terms; and second, his definitions were, for the
most part, well-formed definitional statements.
Between these chapters, he criticized several contemporary economists—Jean-Baptiste Say, David Ricardo, James Mill, John Ramsay McCulloch, and Samuel Bailey—for sloppiness in choosing, attaching meaning to, and using their technical terms.
McCulloch was the editor of The Scotsman of Edinburgh; he replied cuttingly in a review printed on the front page of his newspaper in March, 1827.
He implied that Malthus wanted to dictate terms and theories to other
economists. McCulloch clearly felt his ox gored, and his review of Definitions is largely a bitter defense of his own Principles of Political Economy, and his counter-attack "does little credit to his reputation", being largely "personal derogation" of Malthus. The purpose of Malthus's Definitions
was terminological clarity, and Malthus discussed appropriate terms,
their definitions, and their use by himself and his contemporaries. This
motivation of Malthus's work was disregarded by McCulloch, who
responded that there was nothing to be gained "by carping at
definitions, and quibbling about the meaning to be attached to" words.
Given that statement, it is not surprising that McCulloch's review
failed to address the rules of chapter 1 and did not discuss the
definitions of chapter 10; he also barely mentioned Malthus's critiques
of other writers.
In spite of this, in the wake of McCulloch's scathing review, the
reputation of Malthus as economist dropped away, for the rest of his
life. On the other hand, Malthus did have supporters: Thomas Chalmers, some of the Oriel Noetics, Richard Jones and William Whewell from Cambridge.
Malthus died suddenly of heart disease on 23 December 1834, at his father-in-law's house. He was buried in Bath Abbey. His portrait, and descriptions by contemporaries, present him as tall and good-looking, but with a cleft lip and palate. The cleft palate affected his speech: such birth defects had occurred before among his relatives.
Family
On 13
March 1804, Malthus married Harriet, daughter of John Eckersall of
Claverton House, near Bath. They had a son and two daughters. His
firstborn, son Henry, became vicar of Effingham, Surrey, in 1835, and of Donnington, Sussex, in 1837; he married Sofia Otter (1807–1889), daughter of Bishop William Otter,
and died in August 1882, aged 76. His middle child, Emily, died in
1885, outliving her parents and siblings. The youngest, Lucille, died
unmarried and childless in 1825, months before her 18th birthday.
An Essay on the Principle of Population
Malthus argued in his Essay (1798) that population growth
generally expanded in times and in regions of plenty until the size of
the population relative to the primary resources caused distress:
Yet in all societies, even those that are most vicious, the tendency to a virtuous attachment [i.e., marriage] is so strong that there is a constant effort towards an increase of population. This constant effort as constantly tends to subject the lower classes of the society to distress and to prevent any great permanent amelioration of their condition.
— Malthus, T. R. 1798. An Essay on the Principle of Population. Chapter II, p. 18 in Oxford World's Classics reprint.
Malthus argued that two types of checks hold population within resource limits: positive checks, which raise the death rate; and preventive ones, which lower the birth rate. The positive checks include hunger, disease and war; the preventive checks: birth control, postponement of marriage and celibacy.
The rapid increase in the global population of the past century
exemplifies Malthus's predicted population patterns; it also appears to
describe socio-demographic dynamics of complex pre-industrial societies. These findings are the basis for neo-malthusian modern mathematical models of long-term historical dynamics.
Malthus wrote that in a period of resource abundance, a
population could double in 25 years. However, the margin of abundance
could not be sustained as population grew, leading to checks on
population growth:
If the subsistence for man that the earth affords was to be increased every twenty-five years by a quantity equal to what the whole world at present produces, this would allow the power of production in the earth to be absolutely unlimited, and its ratio of increase much greater than we can conceive that any possible exertions of mankind could make it ... yet still the power of population being a power of a superior order, the increase of the human species can only be kept commensurate to the increase of the means of subsistence by the constant operation of the strong law of necessity acting as a check upon the greater power.
— Malthus T. R. 1798. An Essay on the Principle of Population. Chapter 2, p. 8
In later editions of his essay, Malthus clarified his
view that if society relied on human misery to limit population growth,
then sources of misery (e.g., hunger, disease, and war) would
inevitably afflict society, as would volatile economic cycles. On the
other hand, "preventive checks" to population that limited birthrates,
such as later marriages, could ensure a higher standard of living for
all, while also increasing economic stability.
Regarding possibilities for freeing man from these limits, Malthus
argued against a variety of imaginable solutions, such as the notion
that agricultural improvements could expand without limit.
Of the relationship between population and economics, Malthus
wrote that when the population of laborers grows faster than the
production of food, real wages fall because the growing population
causes the cost of living (i.e.,
the cost of food) to go up. Difficulties of raising a family eventually
reduce the rate of population growth, until the falling population
again leads to higher real wages.
In the second and subsequent editions Malthus put more emphasis on moral restraint as the best means of easing the poverty of the lower classes."
Editions and versions
- 1798: An Essay on the Principle of Population, as it affects the future improvement of society with remarks on the speculations of Mr. Godwin, M. Condorcet, and other writers.. Anonymously published.
- 1803: Second and much enlarged edition: An Essay on the Principle of Population; or, a view of its past and present effects on human happiness; with an enquiry into our prospects respecting the future removal or mitigation of the evils which it occasions. Authorship acknowledged.
- 1806, 1807, 1816 and 1826: editions 3–6, with relatively minor changes from the second edition.
- 1823: Malthus contributed the article on Population to the supplement of the Encyclopædia Britannica.
- 1830: Malthus had a long extract from the 1823 article reprinted as A summary view of the Principle of Population.
Other works
1800: The present high price of provisions
In
this work, his first published pamphlet, Malthus argues against the
notion prevailing in his locale that the greed of intermediaries caused
the high price of provisions. Instead, Malthus says that the high price
stems from the Poor Laws,
which "increase the parish allowances in proportion to the price of
corn." Thus, given a limited supply, the Poor Laws force up the price of
daily necessities. But he concludes by saying that in time of scarcity
such Poor Laws, by raising the price of corn more evenly, actually
produce a beneficial effect.
1814: Observations on the effects of the Corn Laws
Although government in Britain had regulated the prices of grain, the Corn Laws originated in 1815. At the end of the Napoleonic Wars that year, Parliament passed legislation banning the importation of foreign corn into Britain until domestic corn cost 80 shillings per quarter.
The high price caused the cost of food to increase and caused distress
among the working classes in the towns. It led to serious rioting in
London and to the Peterloo Massacre in Manchester in 1819.
In this pamphlet, printed during the parliamentary discussion,
Malthus tentatively supported the free-traders. He argued that given the
increasing cost of growing British corn, advantages accrued from
supplementing it from cheaper foreign sources.
1820: Principles of political economy
In 1820 Malthus published Principles of Political Economy.
1836: Second edition, posthumously published. Malthus intended this work to rival Ricardo's Principles (1817). It, and his 1827 Definitions in political economy, defended Sismondi's views on "general glut" rather than Say's Law, which in effect states "there can be no general glut".
Other publications
- 1807. A letter to Samuel Whitbread, Esq. M.P. on his proposed Bill for the Amendment of the Poor Laws. Johnson and Hatchard, London.
- 1808. Spence on Commerce. Edinburgh Review 11, January, 429–448.
- 1808. Newneham and others on the state of Ireland. Edinburgh Review 12, July, 336–355.
- 1809. Newneham on the state of Ireland, Edinburgh Review 14 April, 151–170.
- 1811. Depreciation of paper currency. Edinburgh Review 17, February, 340–372.
- 1812. Pamphlets on the bullion question. Edinburgh Review 18, August, 448–470.
- 1813. A letter to the Rt. Hon. Lord Grenville. Johnson, London.
- 1817. Statement respecting the East-India College. Murray, London.
- 1821. Godwin on Malthus. Edinburgh Review 35, July, 362–377.
- 1823. The Measure of Value, stated and illustrated
- 1823. Tooke – On high and low prices. Quarterly Review, 29 (57), April, 214–239.
- 1824. Political economy. Quarterly Review 30 (60), January, 297–334.
- 1829. On the measure of the conditions necessary to the supply of commodities. Transactions of the Royal Society of Literature of the United Kingdom. 1, 171–180. John Murray, London.
- 1829. On the meaning which is most usually and most correctly attached to the term Value of a Commodity. Transactions of the Royal Society of Literature of the United Kingdom. 2, 74–81. John Murray.
Reception and influence
Malthus developed the theory of demand-supply mismatches that he called gluts. Discounted at the time, this theory foreshadowed later works of an admirer, John Maynard Keynes.
The vast bulk of continuing commentary on Malthus, however,
extends and expands on the "Malthusian controversy" of the early 19th
century.
In popular culture
- Ebenezer Scrooge from A Christmas Carol by Charles Dickens, represents the perceived ideas of Malthus, famously illustrated by his explanation as to why he refuses to donate to the poor and destitute: "If they would rather die they had better do it, and decrease the surplus population". In general, Dickens had some Malthusian concerns (evident in Oliver Twist, Hard Times and other novels), and he concentrated his attacks on Utilitarianism and many of its proponents, like Bentham, whom he thought of, along with Malthus, as unjust and inhumane people.
- In Aldous Huxley's novel, Brave New World, people generally regard fertility as a nuisance, as in vitro breeding has enabled the society to maintain its population at precisely the level the controllers want. The women, therefore, carry contraceptives with them at all times in a "Malthusian belt".
- Malthus and his ideas feature prominently in Adolfo Bioy Casares's novel The Invention of Morel
- In Robert A. Heinlein's novel The Moon Is a Harsh Mistress, Professor Bernardo de la Paz asks Manuel "Mannie" Garcia O'Kelly-Davis if he has read Malthus. After Mannie tells him he doesn't think so the Professor tells him to read Malthus but not until after their diplomatic work is over since "too many facts hamper a diplomat, especially an honest one." The Professor calls Malthus "a depressing man" and warns Mannie "it is never safe to laugh at Dr. Malthus; he always has the last laugh."
- In George R. R. Martin's science fiction fix-up novel Tuf Voyaging, a planet struggling with overpopulation is named "S'uthlam", an anagram for Malthus.
- In the television show Wiseguy, Kevin Spacey played Mel Proffitt, a self-professed "Malthusian" who quotes Thomas Malthus and keeps a bust of his likeness on display.
- In the show Sliders, episode "Luck of the Draw", the gang slides to an Earth where Malthus’ theories are taken seriously and population is controlled through a lottery.
- At the end of Urinetown, a Broadway musical about a dystopia where, in response to a devastating drought, people too poor to pay for restroom usage are killed as a means of population control, Officer Lockstock cries "Hail, Malthus!" and is echoed by the cast before the last chords of the finale play.
- In the video game Victoria: An Empire Under the Sun the player can research the technology "Malthusian Thought" as a benefit to their country.
- The video game Hydrophobia tells about some eco-terrorists who name themselves "Malthusians" because their ideology is based on Malthus' theories.
- In Marvel's film Avengers: Infinity War, the main villain called Thanos appears to be motivated by Malthusian views about population growth.
Epitaph
The epitaph of Malthus in Bath Abbey reads [with commas inserted for clarity]:
Sacred to the memory of the Rev THOMAS ROBERT MALTHUS, long known to the lettered world by his admirable writings on the social branches of political economy, particularly by his essay on population.
One of the best men and truest philosophers of any age or country, raised by native dignity of mind above the misrepresentation of the ignorant and the neglect of the great, he lived a serene and happy life devoted to the pursuit and communication of truth, supported by a calm but firm conviction of the usefulness of his labours, content with the approbation of the wise and good.
His writings will be a lasting monument of the extent and correctness of his understanding.
The spotless integrity of his principles, the equity and candor of his nature, his sweetness of temper, urbanity of manners and tenderness of heart, his benevolence and his piety are still dearer recollections of his family and friends.
Born February 14, 1766 - Died 29 December 1834.