The term Degrowth (French: décroissance) is used for both a political, economic and social movement as well as a set of theories formulating a critique of the paradigm of economic growth. It is based on ideas from a diverse range of lines of thought such as political ecology, ecological economics, feminist political ecology or environmental justice. Degrowth emphasizes the need to reduce global consumption and production (social metabolism) and advocates a socially just and ecologically sustainable society with well-being as indicator of prosperity instead of GDP. Degrowth highlights the importance of autonomy, care work, self-organization, commons, community, localized production, work sharing, happiness and conviviality.
Background
The movement arose from concerns over the perceived
consequences of the productivism and consumerism
associated with industrial societies (whether
capitalist or socialist) including:
- The reduced availability of energy sources
- The declining quality of the environment
- The decline in the health of flora and fauna upon which humans depend
- The rise of negative societal side-effects
- The ever-expanding use of resources by First World countries to satisfy lifestyles that consume more food and energy, and produce greater waste, at the expense of the Third World
In academia, a study gathered degrowth proposals and defined the movement with three main goals:
(1) Reduce the environmental impact of human activity; (2) Redistribute
income and wealth both within and between countries; (3) Promote the
transition from a materialistic to a convivial and participatory
society.
Resource depletion
As economies grow, the need for resources grows accordingly (unless
there are changes in efficiency or demand for different products due to
price changes). There is a fixed supply of non-renewable resources, such as petroleum (oil), and these resources will inevitably be depleted. Renewable resources can also be depleted if extracted at unsustainable rates over extended periods. For example, this has occurred with caviar production in the Caspian Sea.
There is much concern as to how growing demand for these resources will
be met as supplies decrease. Many organizations and governments look to
energy technologies such as biofuels, solar cells, and wind turbines to
meet the demand gap after peak oil. Others have argued that none of the
alternatives could effectively replace versatility and portability of
oil. Authors of the book Techno-Fix
criticize technological optimists for overlooking the limitations of
technology in solving agricultural and social challenges arising from
growth.
Proponents of degrowth argue that decreasing demand is the only
way of permanently closing the demand gap. For renewable resources,
demand, and therefore production, must also be brought down to levels
that prevent depletion and are environmentally healthy. Moving toward a
society that is not dependent on oil is seen as essential to avoiding societal collapse when non-renewable resources are depleted.
Ecological footprint
The ecological footprint is a measure of human demand on the Earth's
ecosystems. It compares human demand with planet Earth's ecological
capacity to regenerate. It represents the amount of biologically
productive land and sea area needed to regenerate the resources a human
population consumes and to absorb and render harmless the corresponding waste.
According to a 2005 Global Footprint Network report, inhabitants of high-income countries live off of 6.4 global hectares (gHa), while those from low-income countries live off of a single gHa. For example, while each inhabitant of
Bangladesh lives off of what they produce from 0.56 gHa, a North American
requires 12.5 gHa. Each inhabitant of North America uses 22.3 times as
much land as a Bangladeshi. According to the same report, the average
number of global hectares per person was 2.1,
while current consumption levels have reached 2.7 hectares per person.
In order for the world's population to attain the living standards
typical of European countries, the resources of between three and eight
planet Earths would be required with current levels of efficiency and means of production. In order for world economic equality to be achieved with the current available resources, proponents say rich countries would have to reduce their standard of living
through degrowth. The constraints on resources would eventually lead to
a forced reduction in consumption. Controlled reduction of consumption
would
reduce the trauma of this change assuming no technological changes increase the planet's carrying capacity.
Degrowth and sustainable development
Degrowth thought is in opposition to all forms of productivism
(the belief that economic productivity and growth is the purpose of
human organization). It is, thus, opposed to the current form of sustainable development. While the concern for sustainability does not contradict degrowth, sustainable development is rooted in mainstream development ideas that aim to increase capitalist growth and consumption. Degrowth therefore sees sustainable development as an oxymoron, as any development based on growth in a finite and environmentally stressed world is seen as inherently unsustainable.
Critics of degrowth argue that a slowing of economic growth would result in increased unemployment, increased poverty,
and decreased income per capita. Many who understand the devastating
environmental consequences of growth still advocate for economic growth
in the South, even if not in the North. But, a slowing of economic
growth would fail to deliver the benefits of degrowth—self-sufficiency,
material responsibility—and would indeed lead to decreased employment.
Rather, degrowth proponents advocate the complete abandonment of the
current (growth) economic model, suggesting that relocalizing and
abandoning the global economy in the Global South
would allow people of the South to become more self-sufficient and
would end the overconsumption and exploitation of Southern resources by
the North.
"Rebound effect"
Technologies designed to reduce resource use and improve efficiency
are often touted as sustainable or green solutions. Degrowth literature,
however, warns about these technological advances due to the "rebound effect". This concept is based on observations that when a less resource-exhaustive technology is introduced, behavior surrounding the use of that technology may change, and consumption of that technology could increase or even offset any potential resource savings.
In light of the rebound effect, proponents of degrowth hold that the
only effective 'sustainable' solutions must involve a complete rejection
of the growth paradigm and a move toward a degrowth paradigm. There are
also fundamental limits to technological solutions in the pursuit of
degrowth, as all engagements with technology increase the cumulative
matter-energy throughput. However, the convergence of digital commons of knowledge and design with distributed manufacturing technologies may arguably hold potential for building degrowth future scenarios.
Origins of the movement
The contemporary degrowth movement can trace its roots back to the
anti-industrialist trends of the 19th century, developed in Great
Britain by John Ruskin, William Morris and the Arts and Crafts movement (1819–1900), in the United States by Henry David Thoreau (1817–1862), and in Russia by Leo Tolstoy (1828–1910).
The concept of "degrowth" proper appeared during the 1970s, proposed by André Gorz (1972) and intellectuals such as Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen, Jean Baudrillard, Edward Goldsmith, E.F. Schumacher, Erich Fromm, Paul Goodman and Ivan Illich, whose ideas reflect those of earlier thinkers, such as the economist E. J. Mishan, the industrial historian Tom Rolt, and the radical socialist Tony Turner. The writings of Mahatma Gandhi and J. C. Kumarappa also contain similar philosophies, particularly regarding his support of voluntary simplicity.
More generally, degrowth movements draw on the values of humanism, enlightenment, anthropology and human rights.
Club of Rome reports
The world's leaders are correctly fixated on economic growth as the answer to virtually all problems, but they're pushing it with all their might in the wrong direction.
— Donella Meadows, Thinking in Systems
In 1968, the Club of Rome, a think tank headquartered in Winterthur, Switzerland, asked researchers at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology for a report on the limits of our world system and the constraints it puts on human numbers and activity. The report, called The Limits to Growth, published in 1972, became the first significant study to model the consequences of economic growth.
The reports (also known as the Meadows Reports) are not strictly
the founding texts of the degrowth movement, as these reports only
advise zero growth, and have also been used to support the sustainable development
movement. Still, they are considered the first studies explicitly
presenting economic growth as a key reason for the increase in global environmental problems such as pollution, shortage of raw materials, and the destruction of ecosystems. The Limits to Growth: The 30-Year Update was published in 2004, and in 2012, a 40-year forecast from Jørgen Randers, one of the book's original authors, was published as 2052: A Global Forecast for the Next Forty Years.
Lasting influence of Georgescu-Roegen
The degrowth movement recognises Romanian American mathematician, statistician and economist Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen as the main intellectual figure inspiring the movement. In his magnum opus on The Entropy Law and the Economic Process, Georgescu-Roegen argues that economic scarcity is rooted in physical reality; that all natural resources are irreversibly degraded when put to use in economic activity; that the carrying capacity
of Earth—that is, Earth's capacity to sustain human populations and
consumption levels—is bound to decrease sometime in the future as
Earth's finite stock of mineral resources is presently being extracted
and put to use; and consequently, that the world economy as a whole is heading towards an inevitable future collapse.
Georgescu-Roegen's intellectual inspiration to degrowth goes back to the 1970s. When Georgescu-Roegen delivered a lecture at the University of Geneva in 1974, he made a lasting impression on the young and newly graduated French historian and philosopher Jacques Grinevald ,
who had earlier been introduced to Georgescu-Roegen's works by an
academic advisor. Georgescu-Roegen and Grinevald soon became friends,
and Grinevald devoted his research to a closer study of
Georgescu-Roegen's work. As a result, in 1979, Grinevald published a
French translation of a selection of Georgescu-Roegen's articles
entitled Demain la décroissance: Entropie – Écologie – Économie ('Tomorrow, the Decline: Entropy – Ecology – Economy'). Georgescu-Roegen, who spoke French fluently, personally approved the use of the term décroissance
in the title of the French translation. The book gained influence in
French intellectual and academic circles from the outset. Later, the
book was expanded and republished in 1995, and once again in 2006;
however, the word Demain ('tomorrow') was removed from the title of the book in the second and third editions.
By the time Grinevald suggested the term décroissance to
form part of the title of the French translation of Georgescu-Roegen's
work, this term had already disseminated through French intellectual
circles since the early-1970s to signify a deliberate political action
to downscale the economy on a permanent and voluntary basis. Simultaneously, but independently, Georgescu-Roegen criticised the ideas of The Limits to Growth and Herman Daly's steady-state economy
in his pointed and polemical article on "Energy and Economic Myths",
delivered as a series of lectures from 1972 and later at various places,
but not published in print before 1975. In this article,
Georgescu-Roegen stated the following:
[Authors who] were set exclusively on proving the impossibility of growth ... were easily deluded by a simple, now widespread, but false syllogism: Since exponential growth in a finite world leads to disasters of all kinds, ecological salvation lies in the stationary state. ... The crucial error consists in not seeing that not only growth, but also a zero-growth state, nay, even a declining state which does not converge toward annihilation, cannot exist forever in a finite environment.
... [T]he important, yet unnoticed point [is] that the necessary conclusion of the arguments in favor of that vision [of a stationary state] is that the most desirable state is not a stationary, but a declining one. Undoubtedly, the current growth must cease, nay, be reversed. [Emphasis in original]
When reading this particular passage of the text, Grinevald realised
that no professional economist of any orientation had ever reasoned like
this before. Grinevald also realised the striking conceptual
resemblance between Georgescu-Roegen's viewpoint and the French debates
occurring at the time; this resemblance was captured in the title of the
French edition. Taken together, the translation of Georgescu-Roegen's
work into French both fed on and gave further impetus to the concept of décroissance in France—and everywhere else in the francophone world—thereby creating something of an intellectual feedback loop.
By the 2000s, when décroissance was to be translated from
French and back into English as the catchy banner for the new social
movement, the original term "decline" was now deemed inappropriate and
misdirected for the purpose: "Decline" usually refers to an unexpected,
unwelcome and temporary economic recession, something bad to be avoided or quickly overcome. Instead, the neologism
"degrowth" was coined to signify a deliberate political action to
downscale the economy on a permanent and conscious basis—as in the
prevailing French usage of the term—something good to be welcomed and
maintained, or so followers believe.
When the first international degrowth conference was held in
Paris in 2008, the participants honoured Georgescu-Roegen and his work. In his manifesto on Petit traité de la décroissance sereine ("Farewell to Growth"), the leading French champion of the degrowth movement, Serge Latouche, credited Georgescu-Roegen as the "...main theoretical source of degrowth". Likewise, Italian degrowth theorist Mauro Bonaiuti considered Georgescu-Roegen's work to be "one of the analytical cornerstones of the degrowth perspective".
Serge Latouche
Serge Latouche, a professor of economics at the University of Paris-Sud, has noted that:
If you try to measure the reduction in the rate of growth by taking into account damages caused to the environment and its consequences on our natural and cultural patrimony, you will generally obtain a result of zero or even negative growth. In 1991, the United States spent 115 billion dollars, or 2.1% of the GDP on the protection of the environment. The Clean Air Act increased this cost by 45 or 55 million dollars per year. [...] The World Resources Institute tried to measure the rate of the growth taking into account the punishment exerted on the natural capital of the world, with an eye towards sustainable development. For Indonesia, it found that the rate of growth between 1971 and 1984 would be reduced from 7.1 to 4% annually, and that was by taking only three variables into consideration: deforestation, the reduction in the reserves of oil and natural gas, and soil erosion.
Schumacher and Buddhist economics
E. F. Schumacher's 1973 book Small Is Beautiful
predates a unified degrowth movement, but nonetheless serves as an
important basis for degrowth ideas. In this book he critiques the neo-liberal
model of economic development, arguing that an increasing "standard of
living", based on consumption, is absurd as a goal of economic activity
and development. Instead, under what he refers to as Buddhist economics, we should aim to maximize well-being while minimizing consumption.
Ecological and social issues
In January 1972, Edward Goldsmith and Robert Prescott-Allen—editors of The Ecologist—published A Blueprint for Survival, which called for a radical programme of decentralisation and deindustrialization
to prevent what the authors referred to as "the breakdown of society
and the irreversible disruption of the life-support systems on this
planet".
In 2019, a summary for policymakers of the largest, most
comprehensive study to date of biodiversity and ecosystem services was
published by the Intergovernmental Science-Policy Platform on Biodiversity and Ecosystem Services. The report was finalised in Paris. The main conclusions:
1. Over the last 50 years, the state of nature has deteriorated at an unprecedented and accelerating rate.
2. The main drivers of this deterioration have been changes in
land and sea use, exploitation of living beings, climate change,
pollution and invasive species. These five drivers, in turn, are caused
by societal behaviors, from consumption to governance.
3. Damage to ecosystems undermines 35 of 44 selected UN targets, including the UN General Assembly's Sustainable Development Goals
for poverty, hunger, health, water, cities' climate, oceans and land.
It can cause problems with food, water and humanity's air supply.
4. To fix the problem, humanity will need a transformative change, including sustainable agriculture, reductions in consumption
and waste, fishing quotas and collaborative water management. In page 8
the report propose in page 8 of the summary " enabling visions of a
good quality of life that do not entail ever-increasing material
consumption" as one of the main measures. The report states that "Some
pathways chosen to achieve the goals related to energy, economic growth,
industry and infrastructure and sustainable consumption and production
(Sustainable Development Goals 7, 8, 9 and 12), as well as targets
related to poverty, food security and cities (Sustainable Development
Goals 1, 2 and 11), could have substantial positive or negative impacts
on nature and therefore on the achievement of other Sustainable
Development Goals".
Degrowth movement
Conferences
The movement has included international conferences, promoted by the network Research & Degrowth (R&D), in Paris (2008), Barcelona (2010), Montreal (2012), Venice (2012), Leipzig (2014), Budapest (2016), and Malmö (2018).
Barcelona Conference (2010)
The First International Conference on Economic Degrowth for Ecological Sustainability and Social Equity in Paris
(2008) was a discussion about the financial, social, cultural,
demographic, and environmental crisis caused by the deficiencies of capitalism and an explanation of the main principles of degrowth. The Second International Conference in Barcelona focused on specific ways to implement a degrowth society.
Concrete proposals have been developed for future political actions, including:
- Promotion of local currencies, elimination of fiat money and reforms of interest
- Transition to non-profit and small scale companies
- Increase of local commons and support of participative approaches in decision-making
- Reducing working hours and facilitation of volunteer work
- Reusing empty housing and cohousing
- Introduction of the basic income and an income ceiling built on a maximum-minimum ratio
- Limitation of the exploitation of natural resources and preservation of the biodiversity and culture by regulations, taxes and compensations
- Minimize the waste production with education and legal instruments
- Elimination of mega infrastructures, transition from a car-based system to a more local, biking, walking-based one.
- Suppression of advertising from the public space.
The Barcelona conference had little influence on the world economic
and political order. Criticism of the proposals arrived at in Barcelona,
mostly financial, have inhibited change.
Degrowth around the world
Although
not explicitly called degrowth, movements using similar concepts and
terminologies can be found around the world, such as Buen Vivir in Latin America, the Zapatistas in Mexico, the Kurdish Rojava or Eco-Swaraj in India.
Relation to other social movements
The
degrowth movement has a variety of relations to other social movements
and alternative economic visions, which range from collaboration to
partial overlap. The Konzeptwerk Neue Ökonomie (Laboratory for New
Economic Ideas), which hosted the 2014 international Degrowth conference
in Leipzig, has published a project entitled "Degrowth in movement(s)" in 2017, which maps relationships with 32 other social movements and initiatives. The relation to the environmental justice movement is especially visible.
Criticisms, challenges and dilemmas
The
critiques of degrowth concern the negative connotation that the term
"degrowth" carries as well as the fact that growth is seen as
unambiguously bad, the challenges and feasibility of a degrowth
transition as well as the entanglement of desirable aspects of modernity
with the growth paradigm.
Criticisms
Negative connotation
The
use of the term “degrowth” is criticized for being detrimental to the
degrowth movement because it could carry a negative connotation, in opposition to the positively perceived “growth”. “Growth” is associated with the “up” direction and positive experiences, while “down” generates the opposite associations. Research in political psychology
has shown that the initial negative association of a concept, such as
of “degrowth” with the negatively perceived “down”, can bias how the
subsequent information on that concept is integrated at the unconscious
level. At the conscious level, degrowth can be interpreted negatively as the contraction of the economy, although this is not the goal of a degrowth transition, but rather one of its expected consequences. Within the current economic system, a contraction of the economy is associated with a recession and the ensuing austerity measures, job cuts or lower salaries. Noam Chomsky commented on the use of the term "degrowth":
when you say “degrowth” it frightens people. It’s like saying you’re going to have to be poorer tomorrow than you are today, and it doesn’t mean that.
Since "degrowth" contains the term “growth”, there is also a risk of the term having a backfire effect, which would reinforce the initial positive attitude toward growth.
"Degrowth" is also criticized for being a confusing term, since its aim
is not to halt economic growth like the name implies. Instead, agrowth
is proposed as an alternative naming that emphasizes that growth ceases
to be an important policy objective, but that it can still be achieved
as a side-effect of environmental and social policies.
Marxist critique
Traditional Marxists
distinguish between two types of value creation: that which is useful
to mankind, and that which only serves the purpose of accumulating
capital.
Traditional Marxists consider that it is the exploitative nature and
control of the capitalist production relations that is the determinant
and not the quantity. According to Jean Zin, while the justification for
degrowth is valid, it is not a solution to the problem. However, other Marxist writers have adopted positions close to the de-growth perspective. For example, John Bellamy Foster and Fred Magdoff, in common with David Harvey, Immanuel Wallerstein, Paul Sweezy and others focus on endless capital accumulation
as the basic principle and goal of capitalism. This is the source of
economic growth and, in the view of these writers, results in an
unsustainable growth imperative.
Foster and Magdoff develop Marx's own concept of the metabolic rift,
something he noted in the exhaustion of soils by capitalist systems of
food production, though this is not unique to capitalist systems of food
production as seen in the Aral Sea. Many Degrowth theories and ideas are based on neomarxist theory.
Systems theoretical critique
In
stressing the negative rather than the positive side(s) of growth, the
majority of degrowth proponents remains focused on (de-)growth, thus
co-performing and further sustaining the actually criticized
unsustainable growth obsession. One way out of this paradox might be in
changing the reductionist vision of growth as ultimately an economic
concept, which proponents of both growth and degrowth commonly imply,
for a broader concept of growth that allows for the observation of
growth in other function systems of society. A corresponding recoding of growth-obsessed or capitalist organizations has recently been proposed.
Challenges
Political and social spheres
The growth imperative is deeply entrenched in market capitalist societies such that it is necessary for their stability. Moreover, the institutions of modern societies, such as the nation state, welfare, the labor market, education, academia, law and finance, have co-evolved along growth to sustain it.
A degrowth transition thus requires not only a change of the economic
system but of all the systems on which it relies. As most people in
modern societies are dependent on those growth-oriented institutions,
the challenge of a degrowth transition also lies in the individual
resistance to move away from growth.
Agriculture
A degrowth society would require a shift from industrial agriculture to less intensive and more sustainable agricultural practices such as permaculture or organic agriculture, but it is not clear if any of those alternatives could feed the current and projected global population.
In the case of organic agriculture, Germany, for example, would not be
able to feed its population under ideal organic yields over all of its arable lands. Moreover, labour productivity
of non-industrial agriculture is significantly lower due to the reduced
use or absence of fossil fuels, which leaves much less labour for other
sectors.
Dilemmas
Given that modernity has emerged with high levels of energy and material throughput, there is an apparent compromise between desirable aspects of modernity (e.g. social justice, gender equality, high life expectancy, very low infant mortality) and unsustainable levels of energy and material use. Another way of looking at this is through the lenses of the Marxist tradition, which relates the superstructure (culture, ideology, institutions) and the base
(material conditions of life, division of labor). A degrowth society,
by its drastically different material conditions, could produce equally
drastic changes of the cultural and ideological spheres of society. The political economy of global capitalism has generated a lot of bads, such as socioeconomic inequality and ecological devastation, which have engendered a lot of goods through individualization and increased spatial and social mobility. This has allowed social emancipation at the level of gender equality,
disability, sexuality and anti-racism that had no historical precedent.
However, the capitalist system is also built on the exploitation of
women’s reproductive labor as well as the Global South. Sexism and racism and inscribed into its structure. Therefore, some theories (such as Eco-Feminism or Political Ecology) argue that there cannot be equality regarding gender and the hierarchy between the Global North and South within capitalism.
Nevertheless, co-evolving aspects of global capitalism, liberal
modernity and the market society, are closely tied and will be difficult
to separate to maintain liberal and cosmopolitan values in a degrowth society.
Healthcare
It
has been pointed out that there is an apparent trade-off between the
ability of modern healthcare systems to treat individual bodies to their
last breath and the broader global ecological risk of such an energy
and resource intensive care. If this trade-off exists, a degrowth
society would have to choose between prioritizing the ecological
integrity and the ensuing collective health or maximizing the healthcare
provided to individuals.
However, many Degrowth scholars argue that the current system produces
both psychological and physical damage to people. They advocate that the
prosperity of a society shouldn’t be measure with GDP but with
well-being.