An oligopoly (/ɒlɪˈɡɒpəli/, from Ancient Greek ὀλίγος (olígos) "few" + πωλεῖν (poleîn) "to sell") is a market form wherein a market or industry is dominated by a small number of large sellers (oligopolists). Oligopolies can result from various forms of collusion which reduce competition and lead to higher prices for consumers. Oligopolies have their own market structure.
With few sellers, each oligopolist is likely to be aware of the actions of the others. According to game theory, the decisions of one firm therefore influence and are influenced by decisions of other firms. Strategic planning by oligopolists needs to take into account the likely responses of the other market. Entry barriers include high investment requirements, strong consumer loyalty for existing brands and economies of scale.
Description
Oligopoly
is a common market form where a number of firms are in competition. As a
quantitative description of oligopoly, the four-firm concentration ratio
is often utilized. This measure expresses, as a percentage, the market
share of the four largest firms in any particular industry. For example,
as of fourth quarter 2008, if we combine total market share of Verizon
Wireless, AT&T, Sprint, and T-Mobile, we see that these firms,
together, control 97% of the U.S. cellular telephone market.
Oligopolistic competition
can give rise to both wide-ranging and diverse outcomes. In some
situations, particular companies may employ restrictive trade practices (collusion, market sharing etc.) in order to inflate prices and restrict production in much the same way that a monopoly
does. Whenever there is a formal agreement for such collusion, between
companies that usually compete with one another, this practice is known
as a cartel. A prime example of such a cartel is OPEC, which has a profound influence on the international price of oil.
Firms often collude in an attempt to stabilize unstable markets,
so as to reduce the risks inherent in these markets for investment and
product development.
There are legal restrictions on such collusion in most countries. There
does not have to be a formal agreement for collusion to take place
(although for the act to be illegal there must be actual communication
between companies)–for example, in some industries there may be an
acknowledged market leader which informally sets prices to which other
producers respond, known as price leadership.
In other situations, competition between sellers in an oligopoly
can be fierce, with relatively low prices and high production. This
could lead to an efficient outcome approaching perfect competition.
The competition in an oligopoly can be greater when there are more
firms in an industry than if, for example, the firms were only
regionally based and did not compete directly with each other.
Thus the welfare
analysis of oligopolies is sensitive to the parameter values used to
define the market's structure. In particular, the level of dead weight loss is hard to measure. The study of product differentiation indicates that oligopolies might also create excessive levels of differentiation in order to stifle competition.
Oligopoly theory makes heavy use of game theory to model the behavior of oligopolies:
- Stackelberg's duopoly. In this model, the firms move sequentially.
- Cournot's duopoly. In this model, the firms simultaneously choose quantities.
- Bertrand's oligopoly. In this model, the firms simultaneously choose prices.
Characteristics
- Profit maximization conditions
- An oligopoly maximizes profits.
- Ability to set price
- Oligopolies are price setters rather than price takers.
- Entry and exit
- Barriers to entry are high. The most important barriers are government licenses, economies of scale, patents, access to expensive and complex technology, and strategic actions by incumbent firms designed to discourage or destroy nascent firms. Additional sources of barriers to entry often result from government regulation favoring existing firms making it difficult for new firms to enter the market.
- Number of firms
- "Few" – a "handful" of sellers. There are so few firms that the actions of one firm can influence the actions of the other firms.
- Long run profits
- Oligopolies can retain long run abnormal profits. High barriers of entry prevent sideline firms from entering market to capture excess profits.
- Product differentiation
- Product may be homogeneous (steel) or differentiated (automobiles).
- Perfect knowledge
- Assumptions about perfect knowledge vary but the knowledge of various economic factors can be generally described as selective. Oligopolies have perfect knowledge of their own cost and demand functions but their inter-firm information may be incomplete. Buyers have only imperfect knowledge as to price, cost and product quality.
- Interdependence
- The distinctive feature of an oligopoly is interdependence. Oligopolies are typically composed of a few large firms. Each firm is so large that its actions affect market conditions. Therefore, the competing firms will be aware of a firm's market actions and will respond appropriately. This means that in contemplating a market action, a firm must take into consideration the possible reactions of all competing firms and the firm's countermoves. It is very much like a game of chess, in which a player must anticipate a whole sequence of moves and countermoves in order to determine how to achieve his or her objectives; this is known as game theory. For example, an oligopoly considering a price reduction may wish to estimate the likelihood that competing firms would also lower their prices and possibly trigger a ruinous price war. Or if the firm is considering a price increase, it may want to know whether other firms will also increase prices or hold existing prices constant. This anticipation leads to price rigidity as firms will be only be willing to adjust their prices and quantity of output in accordance with a "price leader" in the market. This high degree of interdependence and need to be aware of what other firms are doing or might do is to be contrasted with lack of interdependence in other market structures. In a perfectly competitive (PC) market there is zero interdependence because no firm is large enough to affect market price. All firms in a PC market are price takers, as current market selling price can be followed predictably to maximize short-term profits. In a monopoly, there are no competitors to be concerned about. In a monopolistically-competitive market, each firm's effects on market conditions is so negligible as to be safely ignored by competitors.
- Non-Price Competition
- Oligopolies tend to compete on terms other than price. Loyalty schemes, advertisement, and product differentiation are all examples of non-price competition.
Oligopolies in countries with competition laws
Oligopolies
become "mature" when they realise they can profit maximise through
joint profit maximising. As a result of operating in countries with
enforced competition laws, the Oligopolists will operate under tacit
collusion, which is collusion through an understanding that if all the
competitors in the market raise their prices, then collectively all the
competitors can achieve economic profits close to a monopolist, without
evidence of breaching government market regulations. Hence, the kinked
demand curve for a joint profit maximising Oligopoly industry can model
the behaviours of oligopolists pricing decisions other than that of the
price leader (the price leader being the firm that all other firms
follow in terms of pricing decisions). This is because if a firm
unilaterally raises the prices of their good/service, and other
competitors do not follow then, the firm that raised their price will
then lose a significant market as they face the elastic upper segment of
the demand curve. As the joint profit maximising achieves greater
economic profits for all the firms, there is an incentive for an
individual firm to "cheat" by expanding output to gain greater market
share and profit. In Oligopolist cheating, and the incumbent firm
discovering this breach in collusion, the other firms in the market will
retaliate by matching or dropping prices lower than the original drop.
Hence, the market share that the firm that dropped the price gained,
will have that gain minimised or eliminated. This is why on the kinked
demand curve model the lower segment of the demand curve is inelastic.
As a result, price rigidity prevails in such markets.
Modeling
There is no single model describing the operation of an oligopolistic market.
The variety and complexity of the models exist because you can have two
to 10 firms competing on the basis of price, quantity, technological
innovations, marketing, and reputation. However, there are a series of
simplified models that attempt to describe market behavior by
considering certain circumstances. Some of the better-known models are
the dominant firm model, the Cournot–Nash model, the Bertrand model and the kinked demand model.
Cournot–Nash model
The Cournot–Nash
model is the simplest oligopoly model. The model assumes that there are
two "equally positioned firms"; the firms compete on the basis of
quantity rather than price and each firm makes an "output of decision
assuming that the other firm's behavior is fixed."
The market demand curve is assumed to be linear and marginal costs are
constant. To find the Cournot–Nash equilibrium one determines how each
firm reacts to a change in the output of the other firm. The path to
equilibrium is a series of actions and reactions. The pattern continues
until a point is reached where neither firm desires "to change what it
is doing, given how it believes the other firm will react to any
change."
The equilibrium is the intersection of the two firm's reaction
functions. The reaction function shows how one firm reacts to the
quantity choice of the other firm. For example, assume that the firm 1's demand function is P = (M − Q2) − Q1 where Q2 is the quantity produced by the other firm and Q1 is the amount produced by firm 1, and M=60 is the market. Assume that marginal cost is CM=12.
Firm 1 wants to know its maximizing quantity and price. Firm 1 begins
the process by following the profit maximization rule of equating
marginal revenue to marginal costs. Firm 1's total revenue function is RT = Q1 P = Q1(M − Q2 − Q1) = MQ1 − Q1 Q2 − Q12. The marginal revenue function is .
- RM = CM
- M − Q2 − 2Q1 = CM
- 2Q1 = (M − CM) − Q2
- Q1 = (M − CM)/2 − Q2/2 = 24 − 0.5 Q2 [1.1]
- Q2 = 2(M − CM) − 2Q1 = 96 − 2 Q1 [1.2]
Equation 1.1 is the reaction function for firm 1. Equation 1.2 is the reaction function for firm 2.
To determine the Cournot–Nash equilibrium you can solve the
equations simultaneously. The equilibrium quantities can also be
determined graphically. The equilibrium solution would be at the
intersection of the two reaction functions. Note that if you graph the
functions the axes represent quantities. The reaction functions are not necessarily symmetric.
The firms may face differing cost functions in which case the reaction
functions would not be identical nor would the equilibrium quantities.
Bertrand model
The Bertrand model is essentially the Cournot–Nash model except the strategic variable is price rather than quantity.
The model assumptions are:
- There are two firms in the market
- They produce a homogeneous product
- They produce at a constant marginal cost
- Firms choose prices PA and PB simultaneously
- Firms outputs are perfect substitutes
- Sales are split evenly if PA = PB
The only Nash equilibrium is PA = PB = MC.
Neither firm has any reason to change strategy. If the firm
raises prices it will lose all its customers. If the firm lowers price P
< MC then it will be losing money on every unit sold.
The Bertrand equilibrium is the same as the competitive result. Each firm will produce where P = marginal costs and there will be zero profits. A generalization of the Bertrand model is the Bertrand–Edgeworth model that allows for capacity constraints and more general cost functions.
Oligopolistic market Kinked demand curve model
According to this model, each firm faces a demand curve kinked at the existing price.
The conjectural assumptions of the model are; if the firm raises its
price above the current existing price, competitors will not follow and
the acting firm will lose market share and second if a firm lowers
prices below the existing price then their competitors will follow to
retain their market share and the firm's output will increase only
marginally.
If the assumptions hold then:
- The firm's marginal revenue curve is discontinuous (or rather, not differentiable), and has a gap at the kink
- For prices above the prevailing price the curve is relatively elastic
- For prices below the point the curve is relatively inelastic
The gap in the marginal revenue curve means that marginal costs can fluctuate without changing equilibrium price and quantity. Thus prices tend to be rigid.
Examples
In industrialized economies, barriers to entry have resulted in oligopolies forming in many sectors, with unprecedented levels of competition fueled by increasing globalization.
Market shares in an oligopoly are typically determined by product
development and advertising. For example, there are now only a small
number of manufacturers of civil passenger aircraft, though Brazil (Embraer) and Canada (Bombardier)
have participated in the small passenger aircraft market sector.
Oligopolies have also arisen in heavily-regulated markets such as
wireless communications: in some areas only two or three providers are
licensed to operate.
Worldwide
Aircraft
- Boeing and Airbus have a duopoly over the airliner market.
- General Electric, Pratt and Whitney and Rolls-Royce plc own more than 50% of the marketshare in the airliner engine market.
- Aircraft tires is dominated by a four-firm oligopoly that controls 85% of market share, these firms are Goodyear, Michelin, Dunlop, and Bridgestone.
Finance
- Three credit rating agencies (Standard & Poor's, Moody's, and Fitch Group) dominate their market and extend their crucial importance into the financial sector.
- The accountancy market is dominated by PriceWaterhouseCoopers, KPMG, Deloitte Touche Tohmatsu, and Ernst & Young (commonly known as the Big Four)
- Credit card processing is dominated by Visa and Mastercard.
Food
- Three leading food processing companies, Kraft Foods, PepsiCo and Nestlé, together achieve a large proportion of global processed food sales. These three companies are often used as an example of "Rule of three", which states that markets often become an oligopoly of three large firms.
- Nestlé, The Hershey Company and Mars, Incorporated together make most of the confectionery made worldwide.
Technology
- Intel and AMD are the only two major players in desktop CPU market worldwide.
- Microsoft, Sony, Valve, and Nintendo dominate the video game platform market.
- Nvidia and AMD together make most of the chips for discrete graphics.
Australia
- Most print and online media outlets are owned either by News Corporation or by Fairfax Media
- 60 per cent of grocery revenue goes to Coles Group and Woolworths.
- Banking is dominated by ANZ, Westpac, NAB, and Commonwealth Bank. To an extent this oligopoly is enshrined in law in what is known as the "Four pillars policy", in order to ensure the stability of Australia's banking system.
- Fixed line telecommunications products in Australia are primarily delivered by Telstra, Optus, TPG or increasingly NBN Co. Other brands are virtual network operators (VNO). In the mobile market there are three main operators, Telstra, Optus and Vodafone Hutchison Australia with other mobile virtual network operators (MVNO) selling access to those three networks.
Canada
Media
- Torstar and Postmedia Network dominate the newspaper industry
- Bell Media, Rogers Media, and Corus Entertainment dominate English-language television broadcasting
- Bell Media Radio, Newcap Radio, Rogers Media, and Corus Entertainment dominate the English-language radio industry
- Loblaw Companies, Metro Inc., and Sobeys control the majority of the supermarket industry
Other
- Five companies dominate the banking industry: Royal Bank of Canada, Toronto Dominion Bank, Bank of Nova Scotia, Bank of Montreal, and Canadian Imperial Bank of Commerce
- As of 2008 Rogers Wireless, Bell Mobility and Telus Mobility control a combined 94% of Canada's wireless telecommunications market
- Rogers Communications, Bell Canada, Telus, and Shaw Communications dominate the internet service provider market
- Husky Energy, Imperial Oil, Nexen, Shell Canada, Suncor Energy, Syncrude, and Repsol Oil & Gas Canada dominate the oil and gas sector
India
- The petroleum and gas industry is dominated by Indian Oil, Bharat Petroleum, Hindustan Petroleum, and Reliance Petroleum.
- Most of the telecommunication in India is dominated by Airtel, Vodafone,Idea, BSNL and Reliance Jio
European Union
- The VHF Data Link market as air-ground part of aeronautical communications is controlled by ARINC and SITA, commonly known as the organisations providing communication services for the exchange of data between air-ground applications in the Commission Regulation (EC) No 29/2009.
United Kingdom
- Five banks (Barclays, Halifax, HSBC, Lloyds TSB and Natwest) dominate the UK banking sector, they were accused of being an oligopoly by the relative newcomer Virgin Money.
- Four companies (Tesco, Sainsbury's, Asda and Morrisons) share 74.4% of the grocery market.
- The detergent market is dominated by two players, Unilever and Procter & Gamble.
- Six utilities (EDF Energy, Centrica, RWE npower, E.on, Scottish Power and Scottish and Southern Energy) share 95% of the retail electricity market.
- Four mobile phone networks. Virtual mobile networks like Tesco Mobile have attempted to broaden the market, but there are still just four core network providers in EE, Vodafone, O2 and 3 Mobile.
- Big Four Accounting Firms- (KPMG, PWC, Ernst and Young and Deloitte) These four firms audit 99% of the companies in the FTSE100 and 96% of the companies in the FTSE 250 Index.
United States
Media
- Six movie studios (Walt Disney Pictures, Sony Pictures, Universal Pictures, 20th Century Fox, Paramount Pictures, Warner Bros. Entertainment) receive almost 87% of American film revenues.
- The television and high speed internet industry is mostly an oligopoly of seven companies: The Walt Disney Company, CBS Corporation, Viacom, Comcast, Hearst Corporation, Time Warner, and News Corporation (now 21st Century Fox and News Corp). See Concentration of media ownership.
- In March 2012, the United States Department of Justice announced that it would sue six major publishers for price fixing in the sale of electronic books. The accused publishers are Apple, Simon & Schuster Inc, Hachette Book Group, Penguin Group, Macmillan, and HarperCollins Publishers.
Other
- Four wireless providers (AT&T Mobility, Verizon Wireless, T-Mobile, Sprint Corporation) control 89% of the cellular telephone service market. This is not to be confused with cellular telephone manufacturing, an integral portion of the cellular telephone market as a whole.
- Healthcare insurance in the United States consists of very few insurance companies controlling major market share in most states. For example, California's insured population of 20 million is the most competitive in the nation and 44% of that market is dominated by two insurance companies, Anthem and Kaiser Permanente.
- Mergers among airlines have left the industry in the United States dominated by four main entities – Delta Air Lines, United Airlines, Southwest Airlines and American Airlines – which purposely do not compete on some air travel routes.
- Transcontinental freight lines are vastly controlled by two railroads: Union Pacific Railroad and BNSF Railroad.
- The big box retail industry in the U.S. is dominated by Walmart, Target, and Costco.
- Walgreens and CVS Pharmacy take up 86% of the U.S. pharmacy market.
Demand curve
In an oligopoly, firms operate under imperfect competition. With the fierce price competitiveness created by this sticky-upward demand curve, firms use non-price competition in order to accrue greater revenue and market share.
"Kinked" demand curves are similar to traditional demand curves,
as they are downward-sloping. They are distinguished by a hypothesized
convex bend with a discontinuity at the bend–"kink". Thus the first derivative at that point is undefined and leads to a jump discontinuity in the marginal revenue curve.
Classical economic theory assumes that a profit-maximizing producer with some market power (either due to oligopoly or monopolistic competition)
will set marginal costs equal to marginal revenue. This idea can be
envisioned graphically by the intersection of an upward-sloping marginal
cost curve and a downward-sloping marginal revenue curve (because the
more one sells, the lower the price must be, so the less a producer
earns per unit). In classical theory, any change in the marginal cost
structure (how much it costs to make each additional unit) or the
marginal revenue structure (how much people will pay for each additional
unit) will be immediately reflected in a new price and/or quantity sold
of the item. This result does not occur if a "kink" exists. Because of
this jump discontinuity in the marginal revenue curve, marginal costs could change without necessarily changing the price or quantity.
The motivation behind this kink is the idea that in an
oligopolistic or monopolistically competitive market, firms will not
raise their prices because even a small price increase will lose many
customers. This is because competitors will generally ignore price
increases, with the hope of gaining a larger market share as a result of
now having comparatively lower prices. However, even a large price
decrease will gain only a few customers because such an action will
begin a price war with other firms. The curve is therefore more price-elastic for price increases and less so for price decreases. Theory predicts that firms will enter the industry in the long run.