In economics, a free market is a system in which the prices for goods and services are determined by the open market and by consumers. In a free market, the laws and forces of supply and demand are free from any intervention by a government or other authority and from all forms of economic privilege, monopolies and artificial scarcities. Proponents of the concept of free market contrast it with a regulated market in which a government intervenes in supply and demand through various methods such as tariffs used to restrict trade and to protect the local economy. In an idealized free-market economy, prices for goods and services are set freely by the forces of supply and demand and are allowed to reach their point of equilibrium without intervention by government policy.
Scholars contrast the concept of a free market with the concept of a coordinated market in fields of study such as political economy, new institutional economics, economic sociology and political science. All of these fields emphasize the importance in currently existing market systems of rule-making institutions external to the simple forces of supply and demand which create space for those forces to operate to control productive output and distribution. Although free markets are commonly associated with capitalism within a market economy in contemporary usage and popular culture, free markets have also been advocated by anarchists, socialists and some proponents of cooperatives and advocates of profit sharing. Criticism of the theoretical concept may regard systems with significant market power, inequality of bargaining power, or information asymmetry as less than free, with regulation being necessary to control those imbalances in order to allow markets to function more efficiently as well as produce more desirable social outcomes.
Scholars contrast the concept of a free market with the concept of a coordinated market in fields of study such as political economy, new institutional economics, economic sociology and political science. All of these fields emphasize the importance in currently existing market systems of rule-making institutions external to the simple forces of supply and demand which create space for those forces to operate to control productive output and distribution. Although free markets are commonly associated with capitalism within a market economy in contemporary usage and popular culture, free markets have also been advocated by anarchists, socialists and some proponents of cooperatives and advocates of profit sharing. Criticism of the theoretical concept may regard systems with significant market power, inequality of bargaining power, or information asymmetry as less than free, with regulation being necessary to control those imbalances in order to allow markets to function more efficiently as well as produce more desirable social outcomes.
Economic systems
Laissez-faire economics
The laissez-faire principle expresses a preference for an
absence of non-market pressures on prices and wages such as those from
discriminatory government taxes, subsidies, tariffs, regulations of purely private behavior, or government-granted or coercive monopolies. In The Pure Theory of Capital, Friedrich Hayek argued that the goal is the preservation of the unique information contained in the price itself.
The definition of free market has been disputed and made complex
by collectivist political philosophers and socialist economic ideas. This contention arose from the divergence from classical economists such as Richard Cantillon, Adam Smith, David Ricardo and Thomas Robert Malthus and from the continental economic science developed primarily by the Spanish scholastic and French classical economists, including Anne-Robert-Jacques Turgot, Baron de Laune, Jean-Baptiste Say and Frédéric Bastiat. During the marginal revolution, subjective value theory was rediscovered.
Although laissez-faire has been commonly associated with capitalism, there is a similair economic theory associated with socialism called left-wing or socialist laissez-faire, or free-market anarchism, also known as free-market anti-capitalism and free-market socialism to distinguish it from laissez-faire capitalism. Critics of laissez-faire as commonly understood argue that a truly laissez-faire system would be anti-capitalist and socialist.
Socialist economics
Various forms of socialism based on free markets have existed since the 19th century. Early notable socialist proponents of free markets include Pierre-Joseph Proudhon, Benjamin Tucker and the Ricardian socialists. These economists believed that genuinely free markets and voluntary exchange could not exist within the exploitative conditions of capitalism. These proposals ranged from various forms of worker cooperatives operating in a free-market economy such as the mutualist
system proposed by Proudhon, to state-owned enterprises operating in
unregulated and open markets. These models of socialism are not to be
confused with other forms of market socialism (e.g. the Lange model) where publicly owned enterprises are coordinated by various degrees of economic planning, or where capital good prices are determined through marginal cost pricing.
Advocates of free-market socialism such as Jaroslav Vanek
argue that genuinely free markets are not possible under conditions of
private ownership of productive property. Instead, he contends that the
class differences and inequalities in income and power that result from
private ownership enable the interests of the dominant class to skew the
market to their favor, either in the form of monopoly and market power,
or by utilizing their wealth and resources to legislate government
policies that benefit their specific business interests.
Additionally, Vanek states that workers in a socialist economy based on
cooperative and self-managed enterprises have stronger incentives to
maximize productivity because they would receive a share of the profits
(based on the overall performance of their enterprise) in addition to
receiving their fixed wage or salary.
Socialists also assert that free-market capitalism leads to an
excessively skewed distribution of income which in turn leads to social
instability. As a result, corrective measures in the form of social welfare,
re-distributive taxation and administrative costs are required, but
they end up being paid into workers hands who spend and help the economy
to run. They claim corporate monopolies run rampant in free markets,
with endless agency over the consumer. Thus, free-market socialism
desires government regulation of markets to prevent social instability,
although at the cost of taxpayer dollars.
Georgist economics
For classical economists such as Adam Smith,
the term free market does not necessarily refer to a market free from
government interference, but rather free from all forms of economic
privilege, monopolies and artificial scarcities. This implies that economic rents, i.e. profits generated from a lack of perfect competition, must be reduced or eliminated as much as possible through free competition.
Economic theory suggests the returns to land and other natural resources are economic rents that cannot be reduced in such a way because of their perfect inelastic supply.
Some economic thinkers emphasize the need to share those rents as an
essential requirement for a well functioning market. It is suggested
this would both eliminate the need for regular taxes that have a
negative effect on trade as well as release land and resources that are speculated upon or
monopolised. Two features that improve the competition and free market
mechanisms. Winston Churchill supported this view by the following statement: "Land is the mother of all monopoly". The American economist and social philosopher Henry George, the most famous proponent of this thesis, wanted to accomplish this through a high land value tax that replaces all other taxes. Followers of his ideas are often called Georgists or geoists and geolibertarians.
Léon Walras, one of the founders of the neoclassical economics who helped formulate the general equilibrium theory,
had a very similar view. He argued that free competition could only be
realized under conditions of state ownership of natural resources and
land. Additionally, income taxes could be eliminated because the state
would receive income to finance public services through owning such
resources and enterprises.
Non-laissez-faire capitalist systems
The
stronger incentives to maximize productivity that Vanek conceives as
possible in a socialist economy based on cooperative and self-managed
enterprises might be accomplished in a capitalistic free-market if employee-owned companies were the norm as envisioned by various thinkers including Louis O. Kelso and James S. Albus.
Concepts
Perfect competition and market failure
Conditions that must exist for unregulated markets to behave as free markets are summarized at perfect competition. An absence of any of these perfect competition ideal conditions is a market failure. Most schools of economics
allow that regulatory intervention may provide a substitute force to
counter a market failure. Under this thinking, this form of market
regulation may be better than an unregulated market at providing a free
market.
Supply and demand
Demand for an item (such as goods or services) refers to the market
pressure from people trying to buy it. Buyers have a maximum price they
are willing to pay and sellers have a minimum price they are willing to
offer their product. The point at which the supply and demand curves
meet is the equilibrium price of the good and quantity demanded. Sellers
willing to offer their goods at a lower price than the equilibrium
price receive the difference as producer surplus. Buyers willing to pay for goods at a higher price than the equilibrium price receive the difference as consumer surplus.
The model is commonly applied to wages in the market for labor.
The typical roles of supplier and consumer are reversed. The suppliers
are individuals, who try to sell (supply) their labor for the highest
price. The consumers are businesses, which try to buy (demand) the type
of labor they need at the lowest price. As more people offer their labor
in that market, the equilibrium wage decreases and the equilibrium
level of employment increases as the supply curve shifts to the right.
The opposite happens if fewer people offer their wages in the market as
the supply curve shifts to the left.
In a free market, individuals and firms taking part in these
transactions have the liberty to enter, leave and participate in the
market as they so choose. Prices and quantities are allowed to adjust
according to economic conditions in order to reach equilibrium and
properly allocate resources. However, in many countries around the world
governments seek to intervene in the free market in order to achieve
certain social or political agendas. Governments may attempt to create social equality or equality of outcome by intervening in the market through actions such as imposing a minimum wage (price floor) or erecting price controls
(price ceiling). Other lesser-known goals are also pursued, such as in
the United States, where the federal government subsidizes owners of
fertile land to not grow crops in order to prevent the supply curve from
further shifting to the right and decreasing the equilibrium price.
This is done under the justification of maintaining farmers' profits;
due to the relative inelasticity
of demand for crops, increased supply would lower the price but not
significantly increase quantity demanded, thus placing pressure on
farmers to exit the market.
Those interventions are often done in the name of maintaining basic
assumptions of free markets such as the idea that the costs of
production must be included in the price of goods. Pollution and
depletion costs are sometimes not included in the cost of production (a
manufacturer that withdraws water at one location then discharges it
polluted downstream, avoiding the cost of treating the water), therefore
governments may opt to impose regulations in an attempt to try to
internalize all of the cost of production and ultimately include them in
the price of the goods.
Advocates of the free market contend that government intervention
hampers economic growth by disrupting the natural allocation of
resources according to supply and demand while critics of the free
market contend that government intervention is sometimes necessary to
protect a country's economy from better-developed and more influential
economies, while providing the stability necessary for wise long-term
investment. Milton Friedman pointed to failures of central planning, price controls and state-owned corporations, particularly in the Soviet Union and China while Ha-Joon Chang cites the examples of post-war Japan and the growth of South Korea's steel industry.
Economic equilibrium
With varying degrees of mathematical rigor over time, the general equilibrium theory has demonstrated that under certain conditions of competition the law of supply and demand predominates in this ideal free and competitive market, influencing prices toward an equilibrium that balances the demands for the products against the supplies. At these equilibrium prices, the market distributes the products to the purchasers according to each purchaser's preference or utility for each product and within the relative limits of each buyer's purchasing power. This result is described as market efficiency, or more specifically a Pareto optimum.
This equilibrating behavior of free markets requires certain assumptions about their agents—collectively known as perfect competition—which
therefore cannot be results of the market that they create. Among these
assumptions are several which are impossible to fully achieve in a real
market, such as complete information, interchangeable goods and
services and lack of market power. The question then is what
approximations of these conditions guarantee approximations of market
efficiency and which failures in competition generate overall market
failures. Several Nobel Prizes in Economics have been awarded for analyses of market failures due to asymmetric information.
Low barriers to entry
A free market does not require the existence of competition, however
it does require a framework that allows new market entrants. Hence, in
the lack of coercive barriers, for example, paid licensing certification
for certain services and businesses, competition between businesses
flourishes all through the demands of consumers, or buyers. It often
suggests the presence of the profit motive, although neither a profit motive or profit itself are necessary for a free market. All modern free markets are understood to include entrepreneurs, both individuals and businesses. Typically, a modern free-market economy would include other features such as a stock exchange and a financial services sector, but they do not define it.
Spontaneous order
Friedrich Hayek popularized the view that market economies promote spontaneous order which results in a better "allocation of societal resources than any design could achieve".
According to this view, market economies are characterized by the
formation of complex transactional networks which produce and distribute
goods and services throughout the economy. These networks are not
designed, but they nevertheless emerge as a result of decentralized
individual economic decisions. The idea of spontaneous order is an
elaboration on the invisible hand proposed by Adam Smith in The Wealth of Nations. About the individual, Smith wrote:
By preferring the support of domestic to that of foreign industry, he intends only his own security; and by directing that industry in such a manner as its produce may be of the greatest value, he intends only his own gain, and he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of his intention. Nor is it always the worse for society that it was no part of it. By pursuing his own interest, he frequently promotes that of the society more effectually than when he really intends to promote it. I have never known much good done by those who affected to trade for the public good.
Smith pointed out that one does not get one's dinner by appealing to
the brother-love of the butcher, the farmer or the baker. Rather, one
appeals to their self-interest and pays them for their labor, arguing:
It is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer or the baker, that we expect our dinner, but from their regard to their own self-interest. We address ourselves, not to their humanity but to their self-love, and never talk to them of our own necessities but of their advantages.
Supporters of this view claim that spontaneous order is superior to
any order that does not allow individuals to make their own choices of
what to produce, what to buy, what to sell and at what prices due to the
number and complexity of the factors involved. They further believe
that any attempt to implement central planning will result in more
disorder, or a less efficient production and distribution of goods and
services.
Critics such as political economist Karl Polanyi
question whether a spontaneously ordered market can exist, completely
free of distortions of political policy, claiming that even the
ostensibly freest markets require a state to exercise coercive power in
some areas, namely to enforce contracts, govern the formation of labor unions, spell out the rights and obligations of corporations, shape who has standing to bring legal actions and define what constitutes an unacceptable conflict of interest.
General principles
The Heritage Foundation, a conservative and right-wing think tank based in Washington, D.C. that defines capitalism as the free market which is free from state intervention and government regulation,
tried to identify the key factors necessary to measure the degree of
freedom of economy of a particular country. In 1986, they introduced the
Index of Economic Freedom
which is based on some fifty variables. While this and other similar
indices do not necessarily define a free market, The Heritage Foundation
measures the degree to which a modern economy is free. The variables
are divided into the following major groups:
- Trade policy
- Fiscal burden of government
- Government intervention in the economy
- Monetary policy
- Capital flows and foreign investment
- Banking and finance
- Wages and prices
- Property rights
- Regulation
- Informal market activity
Accoring to The Heritage Foundation, these free market principles are
what helped the United States transition to a free-market economy.
International free trade improved the country and in order for
Americans to prosper from a strong economy they had no choice but to
embrace it.
Each group is assigned a numerical value between 1 and 5 as the index
is the arithmetical mean of the values, rounded to the nearest
hundredth. Initially, countries which were traditionally considered
capitalistic received high ratings, but the method improved over time.
Some economists such as Milton Friedman and other laissez-faire
economists have argued that there is a direct relationship between
economic growth and economic freedom and some studies suggest this is
true.
Ongoing debates exist among scholars regarding methodological issues in
empirical studies of the connection between economic freedom and
economic growth. These debates and studies continue to explore just what
that relationship entails.
The Free Market Monument Foundation defines the principles of a free market as such:
- Individual rights: "We are each created with equal individual rights to control and to defend our life, liberty and property and to voluntary contractual exchange."
- Limited government: "Governments are instituted only to secure individual rights, deriving their just powers from the consent of the governed."
- Equal justice under law: "Government must treat everyone equally; neither rewarding failure nor punishing success."
- Subsidiarity: "Government authority must reside at the lowest feasible level."
- Spontaneous order: "When individual rights are respected, unregulated competition will maximize economic benefit for society by providing the most goods and services possible at the lowest cost."
- Property rights: "Private ownership is the most efficient way to sustainably utilize resources."
- Golden rule: "Deal with others honestly and require honesty in return."
Criticism
Critics of the free market have argued that in real world situations it has proven to be susceptible to the development of price fixing monopolies. Such reasoning has led to government intervention, e.g. the United States antitrust law.
Two prominent Canadian authors argue that government at times has
to intervene to ensure competition in large and important industries. Naomi Klein illustrates this roughly in her work The Shock Doctrine and John Ralston Saul more humorously illustrates this through various examples in The Collapse of Globalism and the Reinvention of the World.
While its supporters argue that only a free market can create healthy
competition and therefore more business and reasonable prices, opponents
say that a free market in its purest form may result in the opposite.
According to Klein and Ralston, the merging of companies into giant
corporations or the privatization of government-run industry and
national assets often result in monopolies or oligopolies requiring
government intervention to force competition and reasonable prices. Another form of market failure is speculation, where transactions are made to profit from short term fluctuation, rather from the intrinsic value of the companies or products. This criticism has been challenged by historians such as Lawrence Reed, who argued that monopolies have historically failed to form even in the absence of anti-trust law.
This is because monopolies are inherently difficult to maintain as a
company that tries to maintain its monopoly by buying out new
competitors, for instance, is incentivizing newcomers to enter the
market in hope of a buy-out.
American philosopher and author Cornel West has derisively termed what he perceives as dogmatic arguments for laissez-faire economic policies as free-market fundamentalism.
West has contended that such mentality "trivializes the concern for
public interest" and "makes money-driven, poll-obsessed elected
officials deferential to corporate goals of profit – often at the cost
of the common good". American political philosopher Michael J. Sandel
contends that in the last thirty years the United States has moved
beyond just having a market economy and has become a market society
where literally everything is for sale, including aspects of social and
civic life such as education, access to justice and political influence. The economic historian Karl Polanyi was highly critical of the idea of the market-based society in his book The Great Transformation, noting that any attempt at its creation would undermine human society and the common good.
Critics of free market economics range from those who reject markets entirely in favour of a planned economy as advocated by various Marxists to those who wish to see market failures regulated to various degrees or supplemented by government interventions. Keynesians
support market roles for government such as using fiscal policy for
economic stimulus when actions in the private sector lead to sub-optimal
economic outcomes of depressions or recessions. Business cycle is used by Keynesians to explain liquidity traps, by which underconsumption occurs, to argue for government intervention with fiscal policy. David McNally
of the University of Houston argues in the Marxist tradition that the
logic of the market inherently produces inequitable outcomes and leads
to unequal exchanges, arguing that Adam Smith's
moral intent and moral philosophy espousing equal exchange was
undermined by the practice of the free market he championed. According
to McNally, the development of the market economy
involved coercion, exploitation and violence that Smith's moral
philosophy could not countenance. McNally also criticizes market
socialists for believing in the possibility of fair markets based on
equal exchanges to be achieved by purging parasitical elements from the
market economy such as private ownership of the means of production, arguing that market socialism is an oxymoron when socialism is defined as an end to wage labour.
Some would argue that only one known example of a true free market exists, namely the black market. The black market is under constant threat by the police,
but under no circumstances do the police regulate the substances that
are being created. The black market produces wholly unregulated goods
and are purchased and consumed unregulated. That is to say, anyone can
produce anything at any time and anyone can purchase anything available
at any time. The alternative view is that the black market is not a free
market at all since high prices and monopolies are often enforced
through murder, theft and destruction. Black markets can only exist
peripheral to regulated markets where laws are being regularly enforced.