Money is any item or verifiable record that is generally accepted as payment for goods and services and repayment of debts, such as taxes, in a particular country or socio-economic context. The main functions of money are distinguished as: a medium of exchange, a unit of account, a store of value and sometimes, a standard of deferred payment. Any item or verifiable record that fulfils these functions can be considered as money.
Money is historically an emergent market phenomenon establishing a commodity money, but nearly all contemporary money systems are based on fiat money. Fiat money, like any check or note of debt, is without use value as a physical commodity. It derives its value by being declared by a government to be legal tender; that is, it must be accepted as a form of payment within the boundaries of the country, for "all debts, public and private". Counterfeit money can cause good money to lose its value.
The money supply of a country consists of currency (banknotes and coins) and, depending on the particular definition used, one or more types of bank money (the balances held in checking accounts, savings accounts, and other types of bank accounts). Bank money, which consists only of records (mostly computerized in modern banking), forms by far the largest part of broad money in developed countries.
Etymology
The word "money" is believed to originate from a temple of Juno, on Capitoline, one of Rome's seven hills. In the ancient world Juno was often associated with money. The temple of Juno Moneta at Rome was the place where the mint of Ancient Rome was located. The name "Juno" may derive from the Etruscan goddess Uni
(which means "the one", "unique", "unit", "union", "united") and
"Moneta" either from the Latin word "monere" (remind, warn, or instruct)
or the Greek word "moneres" (alone, unique).
In the Western world, a prevalent term for coin-money has been specie, stemming from Latin in specie, meaning 'in kind'.
History
The use of barter-like
methods may date back to at least 100,000 years ago, though there is no
evidence of a society or economy that relied primarily on barter. Instead, non-monetary societies operated largely along the principles of gift economy and debt. When barter did in fact occur, it was usually between either complete strangers or potential enemies.
Many cultures around the world eventually developed the use of commodity money. The Mesopotamian shekel was a unit of weight, and relied on the mass of something like 160 grains of barley. The first usage of the term came from Mesopotamia circa 3000 BC. Societies in the Americas, Asia, Africa and Australia used shell money – often, the shells of the cowry (Cypraea moneta L. or C. annulus L.). According to Herodotus, the Lydians were the first people to introduce the use of gold and silver coins. It is thought by modern scholars that these first stamped coins were minted around 650–600 BC.
The system of commodity money eventually evolved into a system of representative money. This occurred because gold and silver merchants or banks would issue receipts to their depositors – redeemable for the commodity money deposited. Eventually, these receipts became generally accepted as a means of payment and were used as money. Paper money or banknotes were first used in China during the Song dynasty. These banknotes, known as "jiaozi", evolved from promissory notes
that had been used since the 7th century. However, they did not
displace commodity money, and were used alongside coins. In the 13th
century, paper money became known in Europe through the accounts of
travelers, such as Marco Polo and William of Rubruck. Marco Polo's account of paper money during the Yuan dynasty is the subject of a chapter of his book, The Travels of Marco Polo, titled "How the Great Kaan Causeth the Bark of Trees, Made Into Something Like Paper, to Pass for Money All Over his Country." Banknotes were first issued in Europe by Stockholms Banco in 1661, and were again also used alongside coins. The gold standard, a monetary system
where the medium of exchange are paper notes that are convertible into
pre-set, fixed quantities of gold, replaced the use of gold coins as
currency in the 17th–19th centuries in Europe. These gold standard notes
were made legal tender,
and redemption into gold coins was discouraged. By the beginning of the
20th century almost all countries had adopted the gold standard,
backing their legal tender notes with fixed amounts of gold.
After World War II and the Bretton Woods Conference, most countries adopted fiat currencies that were fixed to the U.S. dollar.
The U.S. dollar was in turn fixed to gold. In 1971 the U.S. government
suspended the convertibility of the U.S. dollar to gold. After this many
countries de-pegged their currencies from the U.S. dollar, and most of
the world's currencies became unbacked by anything except the
governments' fiat of legal tender and the ability to convert the money
into goods via payment. According to proponents of modern money theory, fiat money is also backed by taxes. By imposing taxes, states create demand for the currency they issue.
Functions
In Money and the Mechanism of Exchange (1875), William Stanley Jevons famously analyzed money in terms of four functions: a medium of exchange, a common measure of value (or unit of account), a standard of value (or standard of deferred payment), and a store of value. By 1919, Jevons's four functions of money were summarized in the couplet:
- Money's a matter of functions four,
- A Medium, a Measure, a Standard, a Store.
This couplet would later become widely popular in macroeconomics textbooks. Most modern textbooks now list only three functions, that of medium of exchange, unit of account, and store of value, not considering a standard of deferred payment as a distinguished function, but rather subsuming it in the others.
There have been many historical disputes regarding the
combination of money's functions, some arguing that they need more
separation and that a single unit is insufficient to deal with them all.
One of these arguments is that the role of money as a medium of exchange is in conflict with its role as a store of value:
its role as a store of value requires holding it without spending,
whereas its role as a medium of exchange requires it to circulate.
Others argue that storing of value is just deferral of the exchange,
but does not diminish the fact that money is a medium of exchange that
can be transported both across space and time. The term "financial
capital" is a more general and inclusive term for all liquid
instruments, whether or not they are a uniformly recognized tender.
Medium of exchange
When money is used to intermediate the exchange of goods and services, it is performing a function as a medium of exchange. It thereby avoids the inefficiencies of a barter system, such as the "coincidence of wants" problem. Money's most important usage is as a method for comparing the values of dissimilar objects.
Measure of value
A unit of account (in economics)
is a standard numerical monetary unit of measurement of the market
value of goods, services, and other transactions. Also known as a
"measure" or "standard" of relative worth and deferred payment, a unit
of account is a necessary prerequisite for the formulation of commercial
agreements that involve debt.
Money acts as a standard measure and common denomination of
trade. It is thus a basis for quoting and bargaining of prices. It is
necessary for developing efficient accounting systems.
Standard of deferred payment
While standard of deferred payment is distinguished by some texts, particularly older ones, other texts subsume this under other functions. A "standard of deferred payment" is an accepted way to settle a debt – a unit in which debts are denominated, and the status of money as legal tender,
in those jurisdictions which have this concept, states that it may
function for the discharge of debts. When debts are denominated in
money, the real value of debts may change due to inflation and deflation, and for sovereign and international debts via debasement and devaluation.
Store of value
To act as a store of value, a money must be able to be
reliably saved, stored, and retrieved – and be predictably usable as a
medium of exchange when it is retrieved. The value of the money must
also remain stable over time. Some have argued that inflation, by
reducing the value of money, diminishes the ability of the money to
function as a store of value.
Properties
To fulfill its various functions, money must have certain properties:
- Fungibility: its individual units must be capable of mutual substitution (i.e., interchangeability).
- Durability: able to withstand repeated use.
- Portability: easily carried and transported.
- Cognizability: its value must be easily identified.
- Stability of value: its value should not fluctuate.
Money supply
In economics, money is any financial instrument
that can fulfill the functions of money (detailed above). These
financial instruments together are collectively referred to as the money supply
of an economy. In other words, the money supply is the number of
financial instruments within a specific economy available for purchasing
goods or services. Since the money supply consists of various financial
instruments (usually currency, demand deposits and various other types
of deposits), the amount of money in an economy is measured by adding
together these financial instruments creating a monetary aggregate.
Modern monetary theory
distinguishes among different ways to measure the stock of money or
money supply, reflected in different types of monetary aggregates, using
a categorization system that focuses on the liquidity
of the financial instrument used as money. The most commonly used
monetary aggregates (or types of money) are conventionally designated
M1, M2 and M3. These are successively larger aggregate categories: M1 is
currency (coins and bills) plus demand deposits (such as checking accounts); M2 is M1 plus savings accounts and time deposits
under $100,000; and M3 is M2 plus larger time deposits and similar
institutional accounts. M1 includes only the most liquid financial
instruments, and M3 relatively illiquid instruments. The precise
definition of M1, M2 etc. may be different in different countries.
Another measure of money, M0, is also used; unlike the other measures, it does not represent actual purchasing power by firms and households in the economy. M0 is base money, or the amount of money actually issued by the central bank
of a country. It is measured as currency plus deposits of banks and
other institutions at the central bank. M0 is also the only money that
can satisfy the reserve requirements of commercial banks.
Creation of money
In current economic systems, money is created by two procedures:
Legal tender, or narrow money (M0) is the cash money created by a Central Bank by minting coins and printing banknotes.
Bank money, or broad money (M1/M2) is the money
created by private banks through the recording of loans as deposits of
borrowing clients, with partial support indicated by the cash ratio. Currently, bank money is created as electronic money.
In most countries, the majority of money is mostly created as
M1/M2 by commercial banks making loans. Contrary to some popular
misconceptions, banks do not act simply as intermediaries, lending out
deposits that savers place with them, and do not depend on central bank
money (M0) to create new loans and deposits.
Market liquidity
"Market liquidity" describes how easily an item can be traded for
another item, or into the common currency within an economy. Money is
the most liquid asset because it is universally recognised and accepted
as the common currency. In this way, money gives consumers the freedom to trade goods and services easily without having to barter.
Liquid financial instruments are easily tradable and have low transaction costs. There should be no (or minimal) spread between the prices to buy and sell the instrument being used as money.
Types
Currently, most modern monetary systems are based on fiat money.
However, for most of history, almost all money was commodity money, such
as gold and silver coins. As economies developed, commodity money was
eventually replaced by representative money, such as the gold standard,
as traders found the physical transportation of gold and silver
burdensome. Fiat currencies gradually took over in the last hundred
years, especially since the breakup of the Bretton Woods system in the early 1970s.
Commodity
Many items have been used as commodity money such as naturally scarce precious metals, conch shells, barley, beads etc., as well as many other things that are thought of as having value.
Commodity money value comes from the commodity out of which it is made.
The commodity itself constitutes the money, and the money is the
commodity. Examples of commodities that have been used as mediums of exchange include gold, silver, copper, rice, Wampum,
salt, peppercorns, large stones, decorated belts, shells, alcohol,
cigarettes, cannabis, candy, etc. These items were sometimes used in a
metric of perceived value in conjunction to one another, in various
commodity valuation or price system economies. Use of commodity money is similar to barter, but a commodity money provides a simple and automatic unit of account for the commodity which is being used as money. Although some gold coins such as the Krugerrand are considered legal tender,
there is no record of their face value on either side of the coin. The
rationale for this is that emphasis is laid on their direct link to the
prevailing value of their fine gold content.
American Eagles are imprinted with their gold content and legal tender face value.
Representative
In 1875, the British economist William Stanley Jevons described the money used at the time as "representative money". Representative money is money that consists of token coins, paper money
or other physical tokens such as certificates, that can be reliably
exchanged for a fixed quantity of a commodity such as gold or silver.
The value of representative money stands in direct and fixed relation to
the commodity that backs it, while not itself being composed of that
commodity.
Fiat
Fiat money or fiat currency is money whose value is not derived from
any intrinsic value or guarantee that it can be converted into a
valuable commodity (such as gold). Instead, it has value only by
government order (fiat). Usually, the government declares the fiat
currency (typically notes and coins from a central bank, such as the Federal Reserve System in the U.S.) to be legal tender, making it unlawful not to accept the fiat currency as a means of repayment for all debts, public and private.
Some bullion coins such as the Australian Gold Nugget and American Eagle are legal tender, however, they trade based on the market price of the metal content as a commodity, rather than their legal tender face value (which is usually only a small fraction of their bullion value).
Fiat money, if physically represented in the form of currency
(paper or coins) can be accidentally damaged or destroyed. However, fiat
money has an advantage over representative or commodity money, in that
the same laws that created the money can also define rules for its
replacement in case of damage or destruction. For example, the U.S.
government will replace mutilated Federal Reserve Notes
(U.S. fiat money) if at least half of the physical note can be
reconstructed, or if it can be otherwise proven to have been destroyed. By contrast, commodity money which has been lost or destroyed cannot be recovered.
Coinage
These factors led to the shift of the store of value being the metal
itself: at first silver, then both silver and gold, and at one point
there was bronze as well. Now we have copper coins and other
non-precious metals as coins. Metals were mined, weighed, and stamped
into coins. This was to assure the individual taking the coin that he
was getting a certain known weight of precious metal. Coins could be
counterfeited, but they also created a new unit of account, which helped lead to banking. Archimedes' principle provided the next link: coins could now be easily tested for their fine
weight of metal, and thus the value of a coin could be determined, even
if it had been shaved, debased or otherwise tampered with.
In most major economies using coinage, copper, silver and gold
formed three tiers of coins. Gold coins were used for large purchases,
payment of the military and backing of state activities. Silver coins
were used for midsized transactions, and as a unit of account for taxes,
dues, contracts and fealty, while copper coins represented the coinage
of common transaction. This system had been used in ancient India since the time of the Mahajanapadas. In Europe, this system worked through the medieval period because there was virtually no new gold, silver or copper introduced through mining or conquest.[citation needed] Thus the overall ratios of the three coinages remained roughly equivalent.
Paper
In pre-modern China, the need for credit and for circulating a medium that was less of a burden than exchanging thousands of copper coins led to the introduction of paper money, commonly known today as banknotes. This economic phenomenon was a slow and gradual process that took place from the late Tang dynasty (618–907) into the Song dynasty (960–1279). It began as a means for merchants to exchange heavy coinage for receipts of deposit issued as promissory notes from shops of wholesalers, notes that were valid for temporary use in a small regional territory. In the 10th century, the Song dynasty government began circulating these notes among the traders in their monopolized
salt industry. The Song government granted several shops the sole right
to issue banknotes, and in the early 12th century the government
finally took over these shops to produce state-issued currency. Yet the
banknotes issued were still regionally valid and temporary; it was not
until the mid 13th century that a standard and uniform government issue
of paper money was made into an acceptable nationwide currency. The
already widespread methods of woodblock printing and then Pi Sheng's movable type printing by the 11th century was the impetus for the massive production of paper money in premodern China.
At around the same time in the medieval Islamic world, a vigorous monetary economy
was created during the 7th–12th centuries on the basis of the expanding
levels of circulation of a stable high-value currency (the dinar). Innovations introduced by Muslim economists, traders and merchants include the earliest uses of credit, checks, promissory notes, savings accounts, transactional accounts, loaning, trusts, exchange rates, the transfer of credit and debt, and banking institutions for loans and deposits.
In Europe, paper money was first introduced in Sweden
in 1661. Sweden was rich in copper, thus, because of copper's low
value, extraordinarily big coins (often weighing several kilograms) had
to be made. The advantages of paper currency were numerous: it reduced
transport of gold and silver, and thus lowered the risks; it made
loaning gold or silver at interest easier, since the specie (gold or
silver) never left the possession of the lender until someone else
redeemed the note; and it allowed for a division of currency into credit
and specie backed forms. It enabled the sale of stock in joint stock companies, and the redemption of those shares in paper.
However, these advantages held within them disadvantages. First,
since a note has no intrinsic value, there was nothing to stop issuing
authorities from printing more of it than they had specie to back it
with. Second, because it increased the money supply, it increased
inflationary pressures, a fact observed by David Hume
in the 18th century. The result is that paper money would often lead to
an inflationary bubble, which could collapse if people began demanding
hard money, causing the demand for paper notes to fall to zero. The
printing of paper money was also associated with wars, and financing of
wars, and therefore regarded as part of maintaining a standing army.
For these reasons, paper currency was held in suspicion and hostility
in Europe and America. It was also addictive, since the speculative
profits of trade and capital creation were quite large. Major nations
established mints to print money and mint coins, and branches of their treasury to collect taxes and hold gold and silver stock.
At this time both silver and gold were considered legal tender, and accepted by governments for taxes. However, the instability in the ratio
between the two grew over the course of the 19th century, with the
increase both in supply of these metals, particularly silver, and of
trade. This is called bimetallism and the attempt to create a bimetallic
standard where both gold and silver backed currency remained in
circulation occupied the efforts of inflationists. Governments at this
point could use currency as an instrument of policy, printing paper
currency such as the United States Greenback,
to pay for military expenditures. They could also set the terms at
which they would redeem notes for specie, by limiting the amount of
purchase, or the minimum amount that could be redeemed.
By 1900, most of the industrializing nations were on some form of
gold standard, with paper notes and silver coins constituting the
circulating medium. Private banks and governments across the world
followed Gresham's Law:
keeping gold and silver paid, but paying out in notes. This did not
happen all around the world at the same time, but occurred sporadically,
generally in times of war or financial crisis, beginning in the early
part of the 20th century and continuing across the world until the late
20th century, when the regime of floating fiat currencies came into
force. One of the last countries to break away from the gold standard was the United States in 1971.
No country anywhere in the world today has an enforceable gold standard or silver standard currency system.
Commercial bank
Commercial bank money or demand deposits
are claims against financial institutions that can be used for the
purchase of goods and services. A demand deposit account is an account
from which funds can be withdrawn at any time by check or cash
withdrawal without giving the bank or financial institution any prior
notice. Banks have the legal obligation to return funds held in demand
deposits immediately upon demand (or 'at call'). Demand deposit
withdrawals can be performed in person, via checks or bank drafts, using
automatic teller machines (ATMs), or through online banking.
Commercial bank money is created through fractional-reserve banking, the banking practice where banks keep only a fraction of their deposits in reserve
(as cash and other highly liquid assets) and lend out the remainder,
while maintaining the simultaneous obligation to redeem all these
deposits upon demand.
Commercial bank money differs from commodity and fiat money in two
ways: firstly it is non-physical, as its existence is only reflected in
the account ledgers of banks and other financial institutions, and
secondly, there is some element of risk that the claim will not be
fulfilled if the financial institution becomes insolvent. The process of
fractional-reserve banking has a cumulative effect of money creation by commercial banks, as it expands money supply (cash and demand deposits) beyond what it would otherwise be. Because of the prevalence of fractional reserve banking, the broad money supply of most countries is a multiple larger than the amount of base money created by the country's central bank. That multiple (called the money multiplier) is determined by the reserve requirement or other financial ratio requirements imposed by financial regulators.
The money supply of a country is usually held to be the total
amount of currency in circulation plus the total value of checking and
savings deposits in the commercial banks in the country. In modern
economies, relatively little of the money supply is in physical
currency. For example, in December 2010 in the U.S., of the $8853.4
billion in broad money supply (M2), only $915.7 billion (about 10%)
consisted of physical coins and paper money.
Digital or electronic
The development of computer technology in the second part of the
twentieth century allowed money to be represented digitally. By 1990, in
the United States all money transferred between its central bank and
commercial banks was in electronic form. By the 2000s most money
existed as digital currency in bank databases. In 2012, by number of transaction, 20 to 58 percent of transactions were electronic (dependant on country).
Non-national digital currencies were developed in the early 2000s. In particular, Flooz and Beenz had gained momentum before the Dot-com bubble. Not much innovation occurred until the conception of Bitcoin in 2009, which introduced the concept of a cryptocurrency – a decentralized trustless currency.
Monetary policy
When gold and silver are used as money, the money supply can grow
only if the supply of these metals is increased by mining. This rate of
increase will accelerate during periods of gold rushes and discoveries, such as when Columbus discovered the New World and brought back gold and silver to Spain, or when gold was discovered in California in 1848. This causes inflation, as the value of gold goes down. However, if the rate of gold mining
cannot keep up with the growth of the economy, gold becomes relatively
more valuable, and prices (denominated in gold) will drop, causing
deflation. Deflation was the more typical situation for over a century
when gold and paper money backed by gold were used as money in the 18th
and 19th centuries.
Modern day monetary systems are based on fiat money and are no
longer tied to the value of gold. The control of the amount of money in
the economy is known as monetary policy. Monetary policy is the process
by which a government, central bank, or monetary authority manages the money supply
to achieve specific goals. Usually the goal of monetary policy is to
accommodate economic growth in an environment of stable prices. For
example, it is clearly stated in the Federal Reserve Act that the Board of Governors and the Federal Open Market Committee should seek "to promote effectively the goals of maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates."
A failed monetary policy can have significant detrimental effects
on an economy and the society that depends on it. These include hyperinflation, stagflation, recession,
high unemployment, shortages of imported goods, inability to export
goods, and even total monetary collapse and the adoption of a much less
efficient barter economy. This happened in Russia, for instance, after
the fall of the Soviet Union.
Governments and central banks have taken both regulatory and free market approaches to monetary policy. Some of the tools used to control the money supply include:
- changing the interest rate at which the central bank loans money to (or borrows money from) the commercial banks
- currency purchases or sales
- increasing or lowering government borrowing
- increasing or lowering government spending
- manipulation of exchange rates
- raising or lowering bank reserve requirements
- regulation or prohibition of private currencies
- taxation or tax breaks on imports or exports of capital into a country
In the US, the Federal Reserve is responsible for controlling the money supply, while in the Euro area the respective institution is the European Central Bank. Other central banks with significant impact on global finances are the Bank of Japan, People's Bank of China and the Bank of England.
For many years much of monetary policy was influenced by an economic theory known as monetarism. Monetarism
is an economic theory which argues that management of the money supply
should be the primary means of regulating economic activity. The
stability of the demand for money prior to the 1980s was a key finding
of Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz supported by the work of David Laidler,
and many others. The nature of the demand for money changed during the
1980s owing to technical, institutional, and legal factors and the influence of monetarism has since decreased.
Counterfeit
Counterfeit money is imitation currency produced without the legal
sanction of the state or government. Producing or using counterfeit
money is a form of fraud or forgery. Counterfeiting is almost as old as
money itself. Plated copies (known as Fourrées) have been found of Lydian coins which are thought to be among the first western coins. Before the introduction of paper money,
the most prevalent method of counterfeiting involved mixing base metals
with pure gold or silver. A form of counterfeiting is the production of
documents by legitimate printers in response to fraudulent
instructions. During World War II, the Nazis forged British pounds and American dollars. Today some of the finest counterfeit banknotes are called Superdollars because of their high quality and likeness to the real U.S. dollar. There has been significant counterfeiting of Euro banknotes and coins since the launch of the currency in 2002, but considerably less than for the U.S. dollar.
Laundering
Money laundering is the process in which the proceeds of crime are
transformed into ostensibly legitimate money or other assets. However,
in a number of legal and regulatory systems the term money laundering
has become conflated
with other forms of financial crime, and sometimes used more generally
to include misuse of the financial system (involving things such as
securities, digital currencies, credit cards, and traditional currency), including terrorism financing, tax evasion, and evading of international sanctions.