Capital accumulation (also termed the accumulation of capital) is the dynamic that motivates the pursuit of profit, involving the investment of money or any financial asset with the goal of increasing the initial monetary value of said asset as a financial return whether in the form of profit, rent, interest, royalties or capital gains.
The aim of capital accumulation is to create new fixed and working
capitals, broaden and modernize the existing ones, grow the material
basis of social-cultural activities, as well as constituting the
necessary resource for reserve and insurance. The process of capital accumulation forms the basis of capitalism, and is one of the defining characteristics of a capitalist economic system.
Definition
The definition of capital accumulation is subject to controversy and ambiguities, because it could refer to:
Most often, capital accumulation involves both a net addition and a redistribution of wealth, which may raise the question of who really benefits from it most. If more wealth is produced than there was before, a society becomes richer; the total stock of wealth increases. But if some accumulate capital
only at the expense of others, wealth is merely shifted from A to B. It
is also possible that some accumulate capital much faster than others. When one person is enriched at the expense of another in circumstances that the law sees as unjust it is called unjust enrichment.
In principle, it is possible that a few people or organisations
accumulate capital and grow richer, although the total stock of wealth
of society decreases.
In economics and accounting, capital accumulation is often equated with investment of profit income or savings, especially in real capital goods. The concentration and centralisation of capital are two of the results of such accumulation (see below).
Capital accumulation refers ordinarily to:
- real investment in tangible means of production, such as acquisitions, research and development, etc. that can increase the capital flow.
- investment in financial assets represented on paper, yielding profit, interest, rent, royalties, fees or capital gains.
- investment in non-productive physical assets such as residential real estate or works of art that appreciate in value.
and by extension to:
- human capital, i.e., new education and training increasing the skills of the (potential) labour force which can increase earnings from work.
- social capital, i.e. the wealth and productive capacity that the people in a society hold in common, rather than as individuals or corporations.
- etc.
Both non-financial and financial capital accumulation is usually needed for economic growth, since additional production usually requires additional funds to enlarge the scale of production. Smarter and more productive
organization of production can also increase production without
increased capital. Capital can be created without increased investment
by inventions or improved organization that increase productivity,
discoveries of new assets (oil, gold, minerals, etc.), the sale of property, etc.
In modern macroeconomics and econometrics the term capital formation is often used in preference to "accumulation", though the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) refers nowadays to "accumulation". The term is occasionally used in national accounts.
Measurement of accumulation
Accumulation can be measured as the monetary value of investments, the amount of income that is reinvested, or as the change in the value of assets owned (the increase in the value of the capital stock). Using company balance sheets, tax data and direct surveys as a basis, government statisticians estimate total investments and assets for the purpose of national accounts, national balance of payments and flow of funds statistics. Usually, the reserve banks and the Treasury provide interpretations and analysis of this data. Standard indicators include Capital formation, Gross fixed capital formation, fixed capital, household asset wealth, and foreign direct investment.
Organisations such as the International Monetary Fund, UNCTAD, the World Bank Group, the OECD, and the Bank for International Settlements used national investment data to estimate world trends. The Bureau of Economic Analysis, Eurostat and the Japan Statistical Office provide data on the US, Europe and Japan respectively.
Other useful sources of investment information are business magazines such as Fortune, Forbes, The Economist, Business Week, etc., and various corporate "watchdog" organisations and non-governmental organization publications. A reputable scientific journal is the Review of Income and Wealth.
In the case of the US, the "Analytical Perspectives" document (an annex
to the yearly budget) provides useful wealth and capital estimates
applying to the whole country.
Demand-led growth models
In macroeconomics, following the Harrod–Domar model, the savings ratio () and the capital coefficient () are regarded as critical factors for accumulation and growth, assuming that all saving is used to finance fixed investment. The rate of growth of the real stock of fixed capital () is:
where is the real national income. If the capital-output ratio or capital coefficient () is constant, the rate of growth of is equal to the rate of growth of . This is determined by (the ratio of net fixed investment or saving to ) and .
A country might, for example, save and invest 12% of its national income,
and then if the capital coefficient is 4:1 (i.e. $4 billion must be
invested to increase the national income by 1 billion) the rate of
growth of the national income might be 3% annually. However, as Keynesian economics points out, savings do not automatically mean investment (as liquid funds may be hoarded for example). Investment may also not be investment in fixed capital (see above).
Assuming that the turnover of total production capital invested
remains constant, the proportion of total investment which just
maintains the stock of total capital, rather than enlarging it, will
typically increase as the total stock increases. The growth rate of
incomes and net new investments must then also increase, in order to
accelerate the growth of the capital stock. Simply put, the bigger
capital grows, the more capital it takes to keep it growing and the more
markets must expand.
The Harrodian model has a problem of unstable static equilibrium,
since if the growth rate is not equal to the Harrodian warranted rate,
the production will tend to extreme points (infinite or zero
production).
The Neo-Kaleckians models do not suffer from the Harrodian instability
but fails to deliver a convergence dynamic of the effective capacity
utilization to the planned capacity utilization.
For its turn, the model of the Sraffian Supermultiplier grants a static
stable equilibrium and a convergence to the planned capacity
utilization.
The Sraffian Supermultiplier model diverges from the Harrodian model
since it takes the investment as induced and not as autonomous. The
autonomous components in this model are the Autonomous Non-Capacity
Creating Expenditures, such as exports, credit lead consumption and
public spending. The growth rate of these expenditures determines the
long run rate of capital accumulation and product growth.
Marxist concept
In Karl Marx's economic theory,
capital accumulation is the operation whereby profits are reinvested
into the economy, increasing the total quantity of capital. Capital was
understood by Marx to be expanding value, that is, in other terms, as a
sum of capital, usually expressed in money, that is transformed through human labor into a larger value and extracted as profits. Here, capital is defined essentially as economic or commercial asset value that is used by capitalists to obtain additional value (surplus-value). This requires property relations which enable objects of value to be appropriated and owned, and trading rights to be established.
Over-accumulation and crisis
The
Marxist analysis of capital accumulation and the development of
capitalism identifies systemic issues with the process that arise with
expansion of the productive forces. A crisis of overaccumulation of capital occurs when the rate of profit
is greater than the rate of new profitable investment outlets in the
economy, arising from increasing productivity from a rising organic composition of capital (higher capital input to labor input ratio). This depresses the wage bill, leading to stagnant wages and high rates of unemployment for the working class
while excess profits search for new profitable investment
opportunities. Marx believed that this cyclical process would be the
fundamental cause for the dissolution of capitalism and its replacement by socialism, which would operate according to a different economic dynamic.
In Marxist thought, socialism would succeed capitalism as the dominant mode of production when the accumulation of capital can no longer sustain itself due to falling rates of profit in real production relative to increasing productivity. A socialist economy
would not base production on the accumulation of capital, instead
basing production on the criteria of satisfying human needs and directly
producing use-values. This concept is encapsulated in the principle of production for use.
Concentration and centralization
According to Marx, capital has the tendency for concentration and centralization in the hands of richest capitalists. Marx explains:
"It is concentration of capitals already formed, destruction of
their individual independence, expropriation of capitalist by
capitalist, transformation of many small into few large capitals....
Capital grows in one place to a huge mass in a single hand, because it
has in another place been lost by many.... The battle of competition is
fought by cheapening of commodities. The cheapness of commodities
demands, caeteris paribus, on the productiveness of labour, and
this again on the scale of production. Therefore, the larger capitals
beat the smaller. It will further be remembered that, with the
development of the capitalist mode of production,
there is an increase in the minimum amount of individual capital
necessary to carry on a business under its normal conditions. The
smaller capitals, therefore, crowd into spheres of production which
Modern Industry has only sporadically or incompletely got hold of. Here
competition rages.... It always ends in the ruin of many small
capitalists, whose capitals partly pass into the hands of their
conquerors, partly vanish."
Rate of accumulation
In Marxian economics, the rate of accumulation
is defined as (1) the value of the real net increase in the stock of
capital in an accounting period, (2) the proportion of realized
surplus-value or profit-income which is reinvested, rather than
consumed. This rate can be expressed by means of various ratios between
the original capital outlay, the realized turnover, surplus-value or
profit and reinvestment's (see, e.g., the writings of the economist Michał Kalecki).
Other things being equal, the greater the amount of profit-income that is disbursed as personal earnings and used for consumption
purposes, the lower the savings rate and the lower the rate of
accumulation is likely to be. However, earnings spent on consumption can
also stimulate market demand
and higher investment. This is the cause of endless controversies in
economic theory about "how much to spend, and how much to save".
In a boom period of capitalism, the growth of investments is cumulative, i.e. one investment leads to another, leading to a constantly expanding market, an expanding labor force, and an increase in the standard of living for the majority of the people.
In a stagnating, decadent capitalism, the accumulation process is increasingly oriented towards investment on military and security forces, real estate, financial speculation, and luxury consumption. In that case, income from value-adding production will decline in favour of interest, rent and tax income, with as a corollary an increase in the level of permanent unemployment.
As a rule, the larger the total sum of capital invested, the higher the return on investment will be. The more capital one owns, the more capital one can also borrow and reinvest at a higher rate of profit or interest. The inverse is also true, and this is one factor in the widening gap between the rich and the poor.
Ernest Mandel
emphasized that the rhythm of capital accumulation and growth depended
critically on (1) the division of a society's social product between necessary product and surplus product, and (2) the division of the surplus product between investment and consumption. In turn, this allocation pattern reflected the outcome of competition
among capitalists, competition between capitalists and workers, and
competition between workers. The pattern of capital accumulation can
therefore never be simply explained by commercial factors, it also
involved social factors and power relationships.
Circuit of capital accumulation from production
Strictly speaking, capital has accumulated only when realized profit income has been reinvested in capital assets. But the process of capital accumulation in production has, as suggested in the first volume of Marx's Das Kapital, at least 7 distinct but linked moments:
- The initial investment of capital (which could be borrowed capital) in means of production and labor power.
- The command over surplus-labour and its appropriation.
- The valorisation (increase in value) of capital through production of new outputs.
- The appropriation of the new output produced by employees, containing the added value.
- The realisation of surplus-value through output sales.
- The appropriation of realised surplus-value as (profit) income after deduction of costs.
- The reinvestment of profit income in production.
All of these moments do not refer simply to an economic or commercial process. Rather, they assume the existence of legal, social, cultural and economic power conditions, without which creation, distribution
and circulation of the new wealth could not occur. This becomes
especially clear when the attempt is made to create a market where none
exists, or where people refuse to trade.
In fact Marx argues that the original or primitive accumulation of capital
often occurs through violence, plunder, slavery, robbery, extortion and
theft. He argues that the capitalist mode of production requires that people be forced to work
in value-adding production for someone else, and for this purpose, they
must be cut off from sources of income other than selling their labor
power.
Simple and expanded reproduction
In volume 2 of Das Kapital, Marx continues the story and shows that, with the aid of bank credit,
capital in search of growth can more or less smoothly mutate from one
form to another, alternately taking the form of money capital (liquid
deposits, securities, etc.), commodity capital (tradeable products, real estate etc.), or production capital (means of production and labor power).
His discussion of the simple and expanded reproduction
of the conditions of production offers a more sophisticated model of
the parameters of the accumulation process as a whole. At simple
reproduction, a sufficient amount is produced to sustain society at the
given living standard; the stock of capital stays constant. At expanded reproduction, more product-value is produced than is necessary to sustain society at a given living standard
(a surplus product); the additional product-value is available for
investments which enlarge the scale and variety of production.
The bourgeois claim there is no economic law
according to which capital is necessarily re-invested in the expansion
of production, that such depends on anticipated profitability, market
expectations and perceptions of investment risk. Such statements only
explain the subjective experiences of investors and ignore the objective
realities which would influence such opinions. As Marx states in Vol.2,
simple reproduction only exists if the variable and surplus capital
realized by Dept. 1—producers of means of production—exactly equals that
of the constant capital of Dept. 2, producers of articles of
consumption (pg 524). Such equilibrium rests on various assumptions,
such as a constant labor supply (no population growth). Accumulation
does not imply a necessary change in total magnitude of value produced
but can simply refer to a change in the composition of an industry (pg.
514).
Ernest Mandel introduced the additional concept of contracted economic reproduction,
i.e. reduced accumulation where business operating at a loss outnumbers
growing business, or economic reproduction on a decreasing scale, for
example due to wars, natural disasters or devalorisation.
Balanced economic growth
requires that different factors in the accumulation process expand in
appropriate proportions. But markets themselves cannot spontaneously
create that balance, in fact what drives business activity is precisely
the imbalances between supply and demand:
inequality is the motor of growth. This partly explains why the
worldwide pattern of economic growth is very uneven and unequal, even
although markets have existed almost everywhere for a very long time.
Some people argue that it also explains government regulation of market
trade and protectionism.
Origins
According to Marx, capital accumulation has a double origin, namely in trade and in expropriation,
both of a legal or illegal kind. The reason is that a stock of capital
can be increased through a process of exchange or "trading up" but also
through directly taking an asset or resource from someone else, without
compensation. David Harvey calls this accumulation by dispossession. Marx does not discuss gifts and grants
as a source of capital accumulation, nor does he analyze taxation in
detail (He couldn't, as he died even before completing his major book,
Das Kapital). Nowadays the tax take is often so large (i.e., 25-40% of
GDP) that some authors refer to state capitalism. This gives rise to a proliferation of tax havens to evade tax liability.
The continuation and progress of capital accumulation depends on
the removal of obstacles to the expansion of trade, and this has
historically often been a violent process. As markets expand, more and
more new opportunities develop for accumulating capital, because more
and more types of goods and services can be traded in. But capital
accumulation may also confront resistance, when people refuse to sell,
or refuse to buy (for example a strike by investors or workers, or consumer resistance).
Capital accumulation as social relation
"Accumulation of capital" sometimes also refers in Marxist writings to the reproduction of capitalist social relations (institutions) on a larger scale over time, i.e., the expansion of the size of the proletariat and of the wealth owned by the bourgeoisie.
This interpretation emphasizes that capital ownership, predicated
on command over labor, is a social relation: the growth of capital
implies the growth of the working class (a "law of accumulation"). In the first volume of Das Kapital Marx had illustrated this idea with reference to Edward Gibbon Wakefield's theory of colonisation:
"...Wakefield discovered that in the Colonies, property in money, means of subsistence, machines, and other means of production, does not as yet stamp a man as a capitalist if there be wanting the correlative — the wage-worker, the other man who is compelled to sell himself of his own free-will. He discovered that capital is not a thing, but a social relation between persons, established by the instrumentality of things. Mr. Peel, he moans, took with him from England to Swan River, West Australia, means of subsistence and of production to the amount of £50,000. Mr. Peel had the foresight to bring with him, besides, 3,000 persons of the working-class, men, women, and children. Once arrived at his destination, “Mr. Peel was left without a servant to make his bed or fetch him water from the river.” Unhappy Mr. Peel, who provided for everything except the export of English modes of production to Swan River!"
In the third volume of Das Kapital, Marx refers to the "fetishism of capital" reaching its highest point with interest-bearing capital, because now capital seems to grow of its own accord without anybody doing anything. In this case,
"The relations of capital assume their most externalised and most fetish-like form in interest-bearing capital. We have here , money creating more money, self-expanding value, without the process that effectuates these two extremes. In merchant's capital, , there is at least the general form of the capitalistic movement, although it confines itself solely to the sphere of circulation, so that profit appears merely as profit derived from alienation; but it is at least seen to be the product of a social relation, not the product of a mere thing. (...) This is obliterated in , the form of interest-bearing capital. (...) The thing (money, commodity, value) is now capital even as a mere thing, and capital appears as a mere thing. The result of the entire process of reproduction appears as a property inherent in the thing itself. It depends on the owner of the money, i.e., of the commodity in its continually exchangeable form, whether he wants to spend it as money or loan it out as capital. In interest-bearing capital, therefore, this automatic fetish, self-expanding value, money generating money, are brought out in their pure state and in this form it no longer bears the birth-marks of its origin. The social relation is consummated in the relation of a thing, of money, to itself.—Instead of the actual transformation of money into capital, we see here only form without content."
Markets with social influence
Product
recommendations and information about past purchases have been shown to
influence consumers choices significantly whether it is for music,
movie, book, technological, and other type of products. Social influence
often induces a rich-get-richer phenomenon (Matthew effect) where popular products tend to become even more popular.